CHAPTER 1
What Is an Asset Class?

Investors have access to a vast array of assets with which to form portfolios, ranging from individual securities to broadly diversified funds. The first order of business is to organize this massive opportunity set into a manageable set of choices. If investors stratify their opportunity set at too granular a level, they will struggle to process the mass of information required to make informed decisions. If, instead, they stratify their opportunity set at a level that is too coarse, they will be unable to diversify risk efficiently. Asset classes serve to balance this trade‐off between unwieldy granularity and inefficient aggregation.

In light of this trade‐off and other considerations, we propose the following definition of an asset class.

An asset class is a stable aggregation of investable units that is internally homogeneous and externally heterogeneous, that when added to a portfolio raises its expected utility without benefit of selection skill, and which can be accessed cost effectively in size.

This definition captures seven essential characteristics of an asset class. Let's consider each one in detail.

STABLE AGGREGATION

The composition of an asset class should be relatively stable. Otherwise, it would require continual monitoring and analysis to ascertain its appropriate composition, and it would demand frequent rebalancing to maintain the appropriate composition. Both efforts could be prohibitively expensive.

Asset classes whose constituents are weighted according to their relative capitalizations are stable, because when their prices change, their relative capitalizations change proportionately. By contrast, a proposed asset class whose constituents are weighted according to attributes that shift through time, such as momentum, value, or size, may not have a sufficiently stable composition to qualify as an asset class. Sufficiency, of course, is an empirical issue. Momentum is less stable than value, which is less stable than size. Therefore, a group of momentum stocks would likely fail to qualify as an asset class, while stocks within a certain capitalization range might warrant status as an asset class. Value stocks reside somewhere near the center of the stability spectrum and may or may not qualify as an asset class.

INVESTABLE

The underlying components of an asset class should be directly investable. If they are not directly investable, such as economic variables, then the investor would need to identify a set of replicating securities that tracks the economic variable. Replication poses two challenges. First, in addition to the uncertainty surrounding the out‐of‐sample behavior of the economic variable itself, the investor is exposed to the uncertainty of the mapping coefficients that define the association between the economic variable and the replicating securities. Second, the optimal composition of the replicating securities changes through time, thereby exposing the investor to additional rebalancing costs.

INTERNALLY HOMOGENEOUS

The components within an asset class should be similar to each other. If they are not, the investor imposes an implicit constraint that two or more distinct groupings within the proposed asset class must be held according to their weights within the asset class. There is nothing to ensure that the weights of distinct groupings within a larger group are efficient. If the proposed asset class is disaggregated into distinct groupings, the investor is free to weight them in such a way that yields maximum efficiency.

Consider, for example, global equities. Domestic equities may behave very differently than foreign equities, and developed market foreign equities may behave differently than emerging market equities. Investors may be able to form a more efficient portfolio by disentangling these equity markets and weighting them based on their respective contributions to a portfolio's expected utility, as opposed to fixing their weights as they appear in a broad global index. Not only might the optimal weights of these components shift relative to each other, but the optimal allocation to equities as a whole might shift up or down relative to the allocation that would occur if they were treated as a unified asset class.

EXTERNALLY HETEROGENEOUS

Each asset class should be sufficiently dissimilar from the other asset classes in a portfolio as well as linear combinations of other asset classes. If the asset classes are too similar to each other, their redundancy will force the investor to expend unnecessary resources analyzing their expected return and risk properties and searching for the most effective way to invest in them.

In Chapter 2 we build portfolios from seven asset classes: U.S. equities, foreign developed market equities, emerging market equities, Treasury bonds, corporate bonds, commodities, and cash equivalents. We considered including intermediate‐term bonds as well. However, the lowest possible tracking error of a portfolio composed of these asset classes with intermediate‐term bonds is only 1.1 percent. Intermediate‐term bonds are, therefore, redundant. The lowest possible tracking error with commodities, by contrast, is 19.5 percent; hence, we include commodities in our menu of asset classes. Although there is no generically correct tracking error threshold to determine sufficient independence, within the context of a particular group of potential asset classes the answer is usually apparent.

EXPECTED UTILITY

The addition of an asset class to a portfolio should raise the portfolio's expected utility. This could occur in two ways. First, inclusion of the asset class could increase the portfolio's expected return. Second, its inclusion could lower the portfolio's risk, either because its own risk is low or because it has low correlations with the other asset classes in the portfolio.

The expected return and risk properties of an asset class should not be judged only according to their average values across a range of market regimes. A particular asset class such as commodities, for example, might have a relatively low expected return and high risk on average across shifting market regimes, but during periods of high financial turbulence could provide exceptional diversification against financial assets. Given a utility function that exhibits extreme aversion to large losses, which typically occur during periods of financial turbulence, commodities could indeed raise a portfolio's expected utility despite having unexceptional expected return and risk properties on average.

It might occur to you that in order to raise a portfolio's expected utility an asset class must be externally heterogeneous. This is true. It does not follow, however, that all externally heterogeneous asset classes raise expected utility. An asset class could be externally heterogeneous, but its expected return may be too low or its risk too high to raise a portfolio's expected utility. Therefore, we could have omitted the criterion of external heterogeneity because it is subsumed within the notion of expected utility. Nonetheless, we think it is helpful to address the notion of external heterogeneity explicitly.

SELECTION SKILL

An asset class should not require an asset allocator to be skillful in identifying superior investment managers in order to raise a portfolio's expected utility. An asset class should raise expected utility even if the asset allocator randomly selects investment managers within the asset class or accesses the asset class passively. Not all investors have selection skill, but this limitation should not disqualify them from engaging in asset allocation.

Think about private equity funds, which are actively managed. Early research concluded that only top‐quartile private equity funds earned a premium over public equity funds.1 If this were to be the case going forward, private equity would not qualify as an asset class, because it is doubtful that the average asset allocator could reliably identify top‐quartile funds prospectively, much less gain access to them. More recent research, however, shows that private equity funds, on average from 1997 through 2014, outperformed public equity funds by more than 5 percent annually net of fees.2 If we expected this outperformance to persist, private equity would qualify as an asset class, because an asset allocator who is unskilled at manager selection could randomly select a group of private equity funds and expect to increase a portfolio's utility.

COST‐EFFECTIVE ACCESS

Investors should be able to commit a meaningful fraction of their portfolios to an asset class without paying excessive transaction costs or substantially impairing a portfolio's liquidity. If it is unusually costly to invest in an asset class, the after‐cost improvement to expected utility may be insufficient to warrant inclusion of the asset class. And if the addition of the asset class substantially impairs the portfolio's liquidity, it could become too expensive to maintain the portfolio's optimal weights or to meet cash demands, which again would adversely affect expected utility.

Collectibles such as art, rare books, stamps, and wine may qualify as asset classes for private investors whose wealth is limited to millions of dollars and who do not have liquidity constraints, but for institutional investors such as endowment funds, foundations, pension funds, and sovereign wealth funds, these collectibles have inadequate capacity to absorb a meaningful component of the portfolio. This distinction reveals that the defining characteristics of an asset class may vary, not in kind, but in degree depending on a particular investor's circumstances.

POTENTIAL ASSET CLASSES

We believe the following asset classes satisfy the criteria we proposed, at least in principle, though this list is far from exhaustive.

Cash equivalents Foreign developed market equities
Commodities Foreign emerging market equities
Domestic corporate bonds Foreign real estate
Domestic equities Infrastructure
Domestic real estate Private equity
Domestic Treasury bonds Timber
Foreign bonds TIPS

The following groupings are often considered asset classes but, in our judgment, fail to qualify for the reasons specified. Obviously, this list is not exhaustive. We chose these groupings as illustrative examples.

Art Not accessible in size
Global equities Not internally homogeneous
Hedge funds Not internally homogeneous and require selection skill
High‐yield bonds Not externally heterogeneous
Inflation Not directly investable
Intermediate‐term bonds Not externally heterogeneous
Managed futures accounts Not internally homogeneous and require selection skill
Momentum stocks Unstable composition

Let's focus on hedge funds for a moment, since many investors treat this category as an asset class. Most hedge funds invest across a variety of asset classes; thus, they are not internally homogeneous. Moreover, they comprise actively managed variants of other asset classes, so they are not externally heterogeneous. Finally, it is unlikely that a random selection of hedge funds will improve a portfolio's expected utility. Rather than treating hedge funds as an asset class, investors should think of them as a management style. The decision to allocate to hedge funds, therefore, should be seen as a second‐order decision. After determining the optimal allocation to asset classes, investors should next consider whether it is best to access the asset classes by investing in passively managed vehicles, separately managed accounts, mutual funds, limited partnerships, or hedge funds.

In the next chapter, we describe the conventional approach for determining the optimal allocation to asset classes.

REFERENCES

  1. S. Kaplan and A. Schoar. 2005. “Private Equity Performance: Returns, Persistence and Capital Flows,” Journal of Finance, Vol. 60, No. 4.
  2. W. Kinlaw, M. Kritzman, and J. Mao. 2015. “The Components of Private Equity Performance,” Journal of Alternative Investments, Vol. 18, No. 2 (Fall).

NOTES

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset