CHAPTER 17
Leveraged Buyouts and Private Equity Financing (Congoleum)

This chapter will introduce the reader to leveraged buyouts (LBOs), which today often take place under the guise of private equity financing. It will explain how LBOs work and where the value created by LBOs comes from. As an example, we will use the 1979 leveraged buyout of Congoleum Corporation. This LBO, many times larger than any prior LBO, served as the template for many future LBOs and for today’s private equity takeovers.1

Congoleum: A Short History

Founded in 1886, Congoleum Narin was a flooring product firm that originally produced flooring from raw materials sourced in the Congo (hence the name Congo-leum). It later began producing linoleum, a flexible vinyl floor covering made from ground cork or wood, oxidized linseed oil with powdered pigments, and organic materials. Congoleum was an early producer of linoleum and owned several patents for improvements they made in the production process.2

In 1968, Bath Industries (a holding firm that owned Bath Iron Works, one of the oldest shipbuilding firms in the United States) acquired control of Congoleum Narin after purchasing 42% of its stock. Bath Industries renamed itself Congoleum Industries in 1975 because floor coverings represented 40% of the postacquisition conglomerate’s sales and 95% of its profits.

The Players

Byron C. Radaker arrived at Congoleum in 1975, became COO in 1976, President and CEO in 1977, and then Chairman in 1980. Byron had previously resigned from Certain Teed Corporation (a building products firm) after allegations of insider self-dealing, which were never proven.

Eddy G. Nicholson had worked as the second in command with J. P. Fuqua (after whom the Duke University business school is named) building conglomerates. Mr. Nicholson joined Congoleum in 1975, became COO at the end of 1978, and then President in 1980.

James Harpel was a Harvard MBA who identified Congoleum as an LBO candidate. And what did Harpel do when he determined Congoleum was a good LBO target? Did he buy the company? Yes and no. He had Century Capital Associates (where he was a managing partner) buy 124,000 shares of Congoleum at just under $13 a share (or a total of about $1.6 million). He then took his idea of turning publicly traded Congoleum into a private firm through a leveraged buyout to the investment banking firm First Boston. Isn’t that insider trading, which is illegal? No, not at all. Jim had an idea and thought it was a good one. He felt he had identified a potential LBO candidate before anyone else. He then bought shares. He was not an insider and was not using any inside, non-public information. Many years later, after becoming quite wealthy, Mr. Harpel endowed a chair at Harvard’s Kennedy School of Government. Why not the business school that gave him the knowledge to become wealthy? Ah, we will discuss that a little later.

First Boston approached the Prudential Insurance Company and some other institutional investors to finance the LBO.3 Why would the firm conducting the LBO approach an insurance firm as a possible investor? Wait and we’ll get there as well.

In early 1980, the various players (First Boston, Mr. Harpel’s Century Capital Associates, various financial institutions including Prudential, and the Congoleum executives Byron C. Radaker and Eddy G. Nicholson) created Fibic Corp., a holding company. Fibic Corp. purchased all the outstanding shares of Congoleum for $445 million (or $38 per share, which represented a premium of more than 50% above the price at which Congoleum was trading at the time).

Leading Up to the LBO: What Makes a Firm a Good LBO Target?

So let’s ask: How does a firm look before an LBO? What was it that Jim Harpel saw that made him believe Congoleum was a takeover target? As we will discuss in more detail, Congoleum was an ideal LBO candidate because of its low debt level and stable cash flows.

Byron Radaker and Eddy Nicholson were hired in 1975 to revive Congoleum. As seen in Table 17.1, Congoleum had experienced disappointing sales and profits from 1973 to 1975. Congoleum’s profits fell from $22.2 million in 1973 to a mere $500,000 in 1974. In 1975, sales fell by almost $111 million (or 30%), while profits rebounded to $9.6 million.

Table 17.1 Congoleum’s Income Statements 1973 to 19787

($000’s) 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978
Net sales 382,065 382,767 272,000 284,735 375,466 558,633
Royalties 6,983 10,080 13,163 17,197
Total revenue 382,065 382,767 278,983 294,815 388,629 575,830
Cost of sales 285,602 323,036 219,182 224,028 285,770 385,851
Selling and general expenses 49,703 53,116 34,441 37,805 55,023 108,648
Operating profit 46,760 6,615 25,360 32,982 47,836 81,331
Other income (loss) 5,171 3,821 3,538 4,281
Interest expense 4,153 6,412 5,192 2,064 1,734 1,266
Profit before tax 42,607 203 25,339 34,739 49,640 84,346
Income tax 19,752 (1,705) 11,985 17,400 24,900 42,600
Loss on discontinued operations (666) (1,380) (3,796) (1,615)
Net profit 22,189 528 9,558 15,724 24,740 41,746
Earnings per share 2.83 0.07 1.25 2.04 2.39 3.58
Dividends per share 0.30 0.40 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.80
Stock price (high) 36 7/8 22.25 13.75 19.38 21.88 26.25
Stock price (low) 12.75 3.83 4.50 12.00 13.25 16.25

How did Byron and Eddy do in their efforts to help sales and profits recover? Pretty well. In just four years (1975–1978), Congoleum’s total revenues had grown to $575.8 million, which was 50.4% above their 1974 levels or an average annual increase of just under 11%. The net profit margin improved to 7.3% of sales, and EPS skyrocketed from $0.07/share in 1974 to $3.58 in 1978. Over the same period, Congoleum increased its dividend payout from $0.40/share to $0.80/share, and the firm’s debt ratio fell from 41% ($78.5 million/$192.3 million) to 8% ($15.4 million/$202.9 million). This does not include excess cash, which the firm clearly had, as shown in Table 17.2, given its $77 million in cash and marketable securities at the end of 1978 (compared to debt of $15.4 million). Wall Street recognized the changes at Congoleum and the firm’s stock price soared from a low of $3.83 in 1974 to a high of $26.25 in 1978.

So, was Congoleum still a “buy” after the stock price had gone up almost 685% in four years? Yes, Congoleum was still a “buy” (most of us can only say so with the benefit of hindsight, but Jim Harpel saw it at the time). At the end of 1978, Congoleum’s stock price was trading at 7.3 times its trailing earnings ($26.30/$3.58).4 At the time, the S&P was trading at about 10 times trailing earnings, with a long run historical average of about 15.5 Congoleum’s stock price therefore had room to grow.

What were Congoleum’s principal businesses? Flooring (40% of sales and 65% of profits), shipbuilding (38% of sales and 21% of profits), and auto repair (22% of sales and 14% of profits).6 How secure and stable are the cash flows on these businesses and what is Congoleum’s business risk? At the time, Congoleum’s flooring business was well protected by the firm’s patents. Also, Congoleum’s shipbuilding operations (i.e., Bath Iron Works) had a huge backlog from U.S. government contracts. Finally, Congoleum’s auto parts business had numerous patents of its own and produced mainly replacement parts, as opposed to supplying the original equipment market (OEM). The replacement parts business was much less cyclical than the OEM business, which depended on the manufacturing of new cars. Thus, all three of Congoleum’s main businesses appeared to have strong, stable cash flows.

How about the two key executives, Bryon and Eddy, were they happy? They were paid base salaries of $370,000 and $295,000 a year respectively, plus stock options. Is that a lot of money? Yes, both back then and to this day, but clearly not enough to be considered wealthy. Even with the huge increase in stock price (remember, they had stock options), the executives may have been looking for some way to increase their compensation. Table 17.2]"?>

So why did Wall Street value Congoleum at only 7.3 times trailing earnings, despite the fact it had strong, stable cash flows and the appearance of good management? One potential reason is that Congoleum’s patents were set to expire soon.8 This meant that Congoleum was a cash cow at the time but would eventually have to figure out how to handle the expiration of its patents. However, this was not Congoleum’s current problem in the late 1970s. The firm’s problem at the time was figuring out what to do with all its cash from its improved operations.

What can firms do with their excess cash? As we have previously noted, there are only five things a firm can do with excess cash:

  1. Pay down debt: Congoleum had already done this and no longer had any significant debt.
  2. Pay more dividends: The firm had done this by increasing dividends from $0.40/ share in 1974 to $0.80/share in 1978, or a dividend yield of 3.1% (the dividend yield is the annual cash dividend payments divided by the firm’s stock price). However, the firm could have increased them further.
  3. Buy back stock: With a multiple of only 7.3 compared to a market average of about 15, it is clear that the market viewed the firm as somewhat stodgy without much upside (flooring, shipbuilding, and auto parts were not seen as sexy growth industries). This seems like an avenue the firm could have explored.
  4. Invest internally to increase growth: The firm was already growing nicely in several stable industries. It is not clear that additional investment in these industries would have provided positive-NPV returns.
  5. Buy other firms: It is not clear if Byron and Eddy wanted to.

This was the Congoleum that Jim Harpel saw and believed was an LBO candidate. After he informed First Boston, they agreed with his analysis and took the idea to Prudential Insurance. Why did First Boston go to another firm? For financing. At the time of the case (1979), investment banks didn’t finance their own deals, and private equity funds did not exist as they do today. First Boston did not want/have the ability to fund the entire transaction, so they contacted an insurance company. Insurance companies were and remain huge investors in the debt and equity markets, as are pension funds. Insurance companies and pension funds are considered institutional investors: they receive insurance premiums and retirement savings up front, which they must invest so they can pay out future claims.

As an interesting aside, Berkshire Hathaway’s core business is insurance. Warren Buffett receives huge amounts of cash from premiums, which he must then invest. While he is known for his ability to invest well, a key part of his success has been obtaining the cash to invest, of which a major part has come from insurance premiums.

Details of the Deal

So how did the Congoleum LBO deal work?9 On July 16, 1979, Fibic Corp. offered $38 a share for all the outstanding shares (a 50% premium over the share price at the time, which was $25 ), or a total of $467.8 million (this included $10.1 million to buy out management’s options, and $10 million in fees), as shown in Table 17.3.

Table 17.2 Congoleum’s Balance Sheets 1973 to 1978

($000’s) 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978
Cash and marketable securities 8,578 10,748 6,428 40,424 12,369 77,254
Receivables 48,212 43,518 28,533 37,478 73,989 64,482
Inventory 67,216 71,022 27,727 33,656 73,318 75,258
Other current assets 14,218 7,258 65,253 34,382 5,679 3,511
Current assets 138,224 132,546 127,941 145,940 165,355 220,505
Net property, plant, and equipment 70,004 79,324 53,113 51,102 71,149 70,777
Goodwill and other 24,616 24,964 48,798 31,320 29,876 31,770
Total assets 232,844 236,834 229,852 228,362 266,380 323,052
Current portion long-term debt 5,170 3,880 2,170 1,939 2,055 460
Accounts payable 25,663 20,534 15,212 18,662 38,391 41,578
Other current liabilities 19,240 15,419 29,419 48,542 46,913 68,359
Current liabilities 50,073 39,833 46,801 69,143 87,359 110,397
Long-term debt 59,330 74,627 52,246 16,596 16,067 14,949
Other long-term liabilities 7,139 8,564 10,489 10,075 9,886 10,221
Total liabilities 116,542 123,024 109,536 95,814 113,312 135,567
Contributed capital 14,967 15,015 15,032 15,390 15,812 16,256
Retained earnings 101,335 98,795 105,284 117,158 137,256 171,229
Total equity 116,302 113,810 120,316 132,548 153,068 187,485
Total liabilities and equity 232,844 236,834 229,852 228,362 266,380 323,052

Table 17.3 Total Purchase Price for Congoleum

Payment to shareholders (11.783 million shares @ $38/share) $447.7 million
Payment to buy out management options $ 10.1 million
Fees $ 10.0 million
Total $467.8 million

Remember, Fibic Corp. was the firm that was created to acquire Congoleum and jointly owned by Prudential, First Boston, Century Capital, Byron, and Eddy.

Prior to the offer, Fibic raised $379.6 million in debt and equity (from the various players), as shown in Table 17.4. Wait a second. Fibic paid $467.8 million but only raised $379.6 million. Is there a math problem here? How could Fibic have paid $88.2 million more than it raised? Where did the extra funds come from? The extra funds came from Congoleum itself. Fibic actually used some of Congoleum’s own money—its pile of cash and marketable securities (i.e., “excess cash”)—to buy Congoleum. Let’s step through this in detail:

  1. A new firm was set up (Fibic) with $379.6 million in cash (this was the money that Fibic raised in debt and equity from its owners—Prudential, First Boston, Century Capital, Byron, and Eddy). Fibic purchased all the assets and liabilities of Congoleum, including the firm’s name, for $447.7 million. Congoleum transferred all its assets and liabilities to Fibic, including (by mid-1979) an estimated $130 million of cash.
  2. Congoleum then had one asset: a receivable from Fibic of $447.7 million. Fibic had all of Congoleum’s assets and liabilities, including a total of $509.6 million cash (the $379.6 of Fibic’s financing plus the approximate $130 million of cash from Congoleum). Fibic also had a debt to Congoleum of $447.7 million. Fibic paid Congoleum the $447.7 million it owed as well as about $10 million in fees and $10.1 million in option payments to Congoleum’s management. Fibic now owned about $41.8 million in cash ($509.6 million – $447.7 million – $20.1 million) as well as all of Congoleum’s former liabilities and noncash assets.
  3. Congoleum ended up with one asset: cash of $447.7 million. Congoleum gave the cash to its old stockholders and dissolved itself.

Table 17.4 Financing the Deal

Bank debt (14%) $125.0 million
Senior notes (11.25%, B+) $113.6 million
Junior notes (12.25%, B–) $ 89.8 million
Total debt $328.4 million
Preferred equity (13.5%, CCC) $ 26.2 million
Common equity $ 25.0 million
Total equity $ 51.2 million
Total financing $379.6 million
Or alternatively:
Bank debt $125 million
Strip financing: Senior notes $113.6 million
Junior notes $ 89.8 million
Preferred equity $ 26.2 million
Common equity $ 16.5 million $246.1 million
Investment bank and management equity $ 8.5 million
Total financing $379.6 million

If we break things down even more:

  1. Before the Deal

    Fibic

    Congoleum

    Cash of $379.6 million

     

    Cash of $130 million

     

     

    All other assets and liabilities

     

     

    (Shipyard, auto parts, flooring, etc.)

     

    Cash of $130 million

     

    All other assets and liabilities

  2. Intermediate Stage of the Deal

    Fibic

    Congoleum

    Cash $509.6 million

     

    Congoleum’s assets and liabilities

     

    Payable Congoleum $447.7 million

    Receivable Fibic $447.7 million

    Payable for fees of $10 million

     

    Payable for options of $10.1 million

     

    Cash payment $447.7 million →

     

  3. After the Deal

Fibic Congoleum
Cash $41.8 million10 Cash $447.7 million
All Congoleum’s other assets and liabilities

In fact, the transaction was much more complicated than that outlined above. A few details: First, Bath Iron Works was a wholly owned subsidiary of Congoleum. This meant Congoleum owned the shares of Bath Iron Works rather than the individual assets and liabilities. To avoid numerous tax issues, Bath Iron Works was sold to Fibic first in a separate transaction for $92.3 million, and later all of Congoleum’s other assets and liabilities were purchased for $355.4 million ($92.3 million plus $355.4 million equals the total of $447.7 million). Second, a shell corporation (Fibic) was set up to facilitate the deal, and it was then liquidated once the deal was done. That is, Fibic became Congoleum (the name was part of the assets purchased). Thus, the new Congoleum instead of having shareholders and being publicly traded, was privately owned by First Boston, Prudential, Century Capital, Byron, and Eddy. Regardless of the accounting and legal details, the essence of the transaction is as described and illustrated above.

Consider this from another viewpoint: Essentially, 11.783 million shares of Congoleum were purchased for $379.6 million, which works out to $32.22 per share ($379.6/11.783). How do you pay only $32.22 a share when you bid $37.50 to the old shareholders? By using the old shareholders’ (Congoleum’s) money to help fund the purchase.

How Was the Deal Financed?

What was the actual funding for the deal (i.e., where did the $379.6 million come from)? Fibic borrowed $125 million in new bank debt. Prudential and other institutional investors purchased $246.1 million of securities through strip financing. First Boston and Century Capital purchased a combined $4.5 million of common stock in the new firm. Management (principally Radaker and Nicholson)11 also purchased a combined $4 million of common stock. The total financing for the deal was therefore $379.6 million from all parties combined.

Strip financing is a technique where the investor buys a “strip” of several different securities simultaneously. The strip is sold as a single security. In this case, the $246.1 million of strips consisted of four different pieces: $113.6 million of senior notes, $89.8 million of subordinated notes, $26.2 of preferred stock, and $16.5 million of common stock. Strips can either be separable or nonseparable. In a separable strip, the various securities can be separated and sold later as individual instruments. In a nonseparable strip, the different securities must remain combined in the same proportion. Congoleum’s strips were nonseparable

The Balance Sheet view of Fibic’s new financing is shown in Table 17.4.

Where did the investment bankers (Century Capital and First Boston) get the $4.5 million they invested? Most of it came from the fees they collected for doing the deal. As noted, total fees were $10 million, which included the money to First Boston and Century Capital as well as a $3 million fee to Lazard Frères & Co. (another investment bank who provided a “fairness” opinion on the deal) and the fees to accountants and attorneys.12 Where did management get the $4 million they invested? They were paid $10.1 million for their stock options in the old firm and invested $4 million of that into the deal.

So when the smoke clears, what did the new Congoleum’s Balance Sheet look like? Table 17.5 shows the restated 1978 debt and equity after the LBO. The new firm still retained old Congoleum’s debt of $15.4 million (1978 year-end) plus the new debt of $328.4 million described above for total debt of $343.8 million. Comparing this with the preferred and common equity of $51.2 million, the firm increased its debt ratio (debt/(debt + equity)) from 7.6% ($15.4 million/($15.4 million + $187.5 million)) to 87.0% ($343.8 million/($343.8 million + $51.2 million))—this ignores for the moment the excess cash available on old Congoleum’s Balance Sheet. We discuss all of this in more detail in Appendix 17A for those who want it.

Table 17.5 Condensed Liabilities and Owner Equity in 1978

Without LBO Projected After LBO
Debt $ 15.4 million +$328.4 new debt $343.8 million
Equity $187.5 million restated $ 51.2 million
Debt/(debt + equity) 7.6% 87.0%

Wow! This is a huge increase in leverage. Given our discussion on capital structure earlier in this book, it also should represent a huge increase in financial risk. But is this right? Was the new debt (and risk level) really this high? No. Why not? Look closely again at the debt and equity components in Table 17.4. Let’s consider Congoleum’s common stock. There was a total $25.0 million of common stock. It was split between the $16.5 million owned by Prudential, $4.5 million by First Boston and Century Capital, and $4 million by management (Byron and Eddy). In other words, Prudential owned 66% of the common stock, with First Boston and Century Capital owning 18% while Bryon, Eddy, and a few others owned 16%.

Next, let’s consider Congoleum’s bank debt. What happens if post-LBO Congoleum fails to pay its pre-LBO debt or any new bank debt incurred? The firm risks being forced into bankruptcy.

But what would happen if Congoleum fails to pay the senior or subordinated notes? Remember, Prudential’s senior notes and subordinated notes were tied in with its preferred and common equity and sold as nonseparable strips. This is a critical detail. Would Prudential really have sued Congoleum and put the firm into bankruptcy? If Prudential had been willing to do this, who would it have hurt? The equity holders would have been hurt; however, Prudential was one of the equity holders and owned 66% of Congoleum’s equity after the LBO! Essentially, the senior notes and the subordinated notes were not debt in the traditional sense because this debt was held by the equity holders and couldn’t be separated from the equity. In a very important sense (that of the risk of being forced into bankruptcy), it is not debt. In effect, if Prudential forces bankruptcy, it is harming itself.

The bank debt and old debt were therefore the only “true” debt that added financial risk to Congoleum in the way we discussed in Chapter 6. This meant the new post-LBO firm’s “true” debt was really only 35.5% of total financing (($15.4 million of old debt + $125 million of bank debt) / $395 million of debt plus equity). A 35.5% “true” debt level with cash flows as stable as Congoleum’s was relatively safe with a low risk of bankruptcy.

Thus, the debt ratio may appear to have been 87% (total debt of $343.8 million/$395 million in total debt and equity), but in reality it was not. Prudential owned 59.2% of the debt and 66% of the common stock in strips. The “true” debt level was actually 35.5% as previously noted.

Let’s consider this situation again using a simple example. Imagine you start your own firm in your garage and lend yourself money. You own all the stock. If you can’t pay yourself back the money you lent yourself, are you going to take yourself to court and force yourself into bankruptcy? No. Similarly, as long as Congoleum paid the old debt and the bank debt, it was safe from bankruptcy. Congoleum did not face a substantial risk of bankruptcy if it failed to repay Prudential because the insurance company owned the senior debt, the subordinated debt, the preferred stock, and most of the common stock. So the strip was not really debt in the traditional sense that we talked about earlier in the book (i.e., in the sense of adding to the risk of being forced into bankruptcy in the event of being unable to repay debt).

So, how risky were the old debt and bank debt? The interest on the old debt was about $1.2 million, and the interest on the bank debt was about $17.5 million. This means Congoleum needed to earn $18.7 million to cover the interest on the old debt and bank debt. Table 17.1 showed that in 1978, Congoleum had EBIT of $85.6 million. This was a coverage ratio of 4.6 times. Note that Congoleum’s $17.2 million of royalties alone in 1978 were enough to cover 92% of the interest charges. This shows that Congoleum could easily pay the interest on its old debt and bank debt, and that its risk was not high.

Now, let’s explain the Congoleum LBO another way, using what we know about capital structure theory. Remember that in a pure M&M world with no taxes, capital structure doesn’t matter. By contrast, in an M&M world with taxes and no costs of financial distress, the desired amount of debt is 100%. However, in the real world, as we add debt, we usually add costs of financial distress, so the optimal capital structure depends on the trade-off between the benefit of tax shields and the costs of financial distress. Thus, in determining target capital structure for an LBO, we need to understand the amount of financial distress the LBO has.

To restate our earlier question: Is there any financial distress associated with the strips used to finance the LBO of Congoleum? Not really. By using these nondetachable strips to finance the LBO, First Boston created an M&M world with taxes and very little costs of financial distress. So the optimal amount of debt in this case was much higher than if the firm had to consider the usual higher costs of financial distress.

We should have convinced you by now that the strips used in the Congoleum LBO were not really debt since they didn’t increase the financial risk of the firm. However, let’s add more evidence.

As can be seen from Table 17.4, where the strip is broken down into its various components, the interest rate on the senior notes was 11.25%. The interest rate on the subordinated notes was 12.25%. The preferred stock was paying a dividend of $11 per share, or about 13.5% ($11/$81.25 issue price per share). And the ratings on these three instruments were B+, B–, and CCC respectively.

What was the rate on the new bank debt at the time? About 14%. Let this sink in. What was the most senior debt in this firm? The bank debt was the most senior.13 Who had to get paid first? The holders of the most senior debt, which in this case were the banks. What was the rate on this senior debt? About 14%. Who came after the banks? The holders of the senior notes (otherwise known as senior debentures). What was the rate on the senior notes? 11.25%. And the subordinated notes only received 12.25%.

Note, the yield curve was flat for 1978 and slightly rising in 1979. (One-year government rates were 9.28% and 30-year rates were 10.65%.) This means the rate difference between Congoleum’s senior debt and junior debt is not due to different lengths to maturity.

Does the interest rate on senior debt make sense? If the senior debt was getting 14%, what rate should the junior debt have gotten? Typically higher than the senior debt, because it has more risk. So why did Prudential, which owned the junior debt, accept a lower interest rate than the bank, which owned the senior debt? Because the debt that Prudential owned was not really debt. Prudential was going to get the remainder of its return on the equity it owned. It was therefore willing to accept a lower rate on the senior and subordinated notes. Furthermore, Prudential kept the interest rates on the notes low enough so that Congoleum’s cash flows could pay off the debt without technically defaulting. Thus, the fact that the senior debt (the bank debt) got 14% and the junior debt got at most 12.25% also tells us that the junior debt was not really debt in the traditional sense.

The strips more closely represented equity, since the majority equity holder (Prudential) also owned the strips. So why use strips, why not just use equity? Because if the firm called the strips equity and paid dividends, then the firm would have had to pay taxes before it paid the dividends. But if the firm called the strips debt and paid interest, the firm got to deduct the interest and reduce the amount it owed in taxes.

What was the key result of the LBO? Congoleum basically swapped out one stockholder for another: the firm swapped out the public stockholders for the private ones. To do this, it used a brilliant financing structure. By using strip financing, Congoleum was able to increase its nominal debt level and reduce taxes without a corresponding increase in financial distress.

This was the very first LBO with this structure (i.e., with strip financing). It was also five times larger than any LBO ever done before. The Congoleum LBO became the blueprint for future LBOs, and it started the LBO—and now, private equity—boom. We will discuss below how the equity return compensated Prudential and made up for the low rate it got on the debt it owned.

Risk of the LBO

Let us now revisit: What was the basic business risk (BBR) of Congoleum? Since Congoleum had three distinct product lines, another way of asking this is: How much risk was there in each of the three businesses? Not very much. As previously noted, this was why the firm was such a good LBO candidate. Home furnishing had a very low basic business risk with Congoleum’s patents and brand name (Congoleum flooring is still in the market today, 35 years later). Shipbuilding had a very low BBR because they were a government contractor with a multiyear backlog. The auto part business had low risk because it also had numerous patents, plus it sold in the maintenance market (less risky than the original equipment market). Furthermore, if cash flows turned out to be lower than forecasted, Congoleum could have easily divested one of these divisions for funds because none were critical to any other.

So let’s ask: What are the expected cash flows? Later in this chapter, we will calculate pro formas for the LBO; we find there is very strong cash flows and very little risk to the debt holders.14 The coverage ratio (EBIT/interest) we project is strong and improves over time (from 1.38 to 5.74, as shown in Table 17.9), and the cash flows are stable. Importantly, the royalties to Congoleum from its patents remain equal to half the projected total interest payments. The combination of low BBR with stable cash flows, the ability to sell off a division, improving coverage ratios, and a “real” debt level of only 35.5% provided great comfort to the lenders.

Table 17.6 Congoleum Pro Forma 1980 Income Statement without and with the LBO

($000’s) Without LBO Projected 1980 With LBO Projected 1980 Difference
Total revenues 709.5 709.5 0.0
Cost of sales 475.4 475.4 0.0
SG&A 134.8 176.8 42.0
Operating profit 99.3 57.3 −42.0
Interest expense 0.0 41.6 −41.6
Miscellaneous 0.0 0.0 0.0
Income before tax 99.3 15.7 −83.6
Income tax (48%) 47.7 7.5 −40.2
Net income 51.6 8.2 −43.2

What about the management of Congoleum? Was it good management? Would investors have been worried that management might leave? We know the management at the time was able to run the company because they had done a good job in the past. In addition, with the LBO, management would now own a substantial portion of the equity in Congoleum, providing them with added incentive and thus making them unlikely to leave.

So what was the risk from the bank’s point of view? Low to moderate. This was a stable company with good cash flows, good collateral, good management, and a low-to-moderate “actual” debt level. The bank owned $125 million of debt, which was 32% of total capital and was all senior debt.

How about the risk from Prudential’s point of view? Congoleum’s total debt level with all debt included—regardless of its being “actual” or not—was 87% ($343 million/$395 million). Of this total debt, Prudential had 59% ($203.4 million/$343 million), all of which was junior. Without the equity component, this would have made Prudential’s position quite risky, even given the stable cash flows and low business risk. However, Prudential also owned 66% of Congoleum’s equity. This means its position should be viewed as that of an equity holder, not a debt holder. And while this equity position was riskier than the bank’s position, Prudential (like any equity holder) also had a potential upside. Furthermore, unlike a typical equity holder in a firm with 87% debt, Prudential also owned much of the debt. As such, the risk of financial distress from the junior debt is not that high. Prudential, as the majority equity holder, would not have forced Congoleum (mostly owned by itself) into bankruptcy.

Value Creation

We stated earlier that the LBO structure used in Congoleum created value. How much value did the LBO create? Well, on July 15, 1979, Congoleum’s share price was $25 a share. Since there were 11.783 million shares outstanding, this means Congoleum’s market capitalization (market cap) was $299 million. This was the market value of the equity. On July 16, 1979, the consortium of Prudential, First Boston, Century Capital, and Congoleum’s management made a tender offer to the current shareholders at $38 a share. This means the bid for all of the 11.783 million shares was for a total of $447.7 million. The market value of equity went up by $148.7 million ($447.7 million – $299.0 million) in one day, a 50% premium. How did the market value of equity go up by so much with the tender offer?

Through the miracle of modern finance!

July 15, 1979 July 16, 1979
Price per share $25.375 $38.00
Shares outstanding 11.783 million 11.783 million
Market value of shares $299.0 million $447.7 million

The operations of Congoleum did not change in any way as a result of the LBO, nor were they expected to.

Was it the same company? Yes.
Did the firm have the same management? Yes.
Had the firm sold off or acquired any businesses? No.
Were there any synergy stories to tell here? No.
Were there increasing sales? No.
New labor contracts? No.

Congoleum went from being a public firm worth $299 million to being a private firm worth $467.8 million (the price paid). Where did the additional value come? Let’s take a look.

Congoleum’s Pro Formas

Let’s put ourselves in July 1979 as the present and generate pro formas for Congoleum with and without the LBO. Since this chapter is not about pro formas (which we explained earlier in the book), the pro formas can be found in Appendix 17A. Note that there are two significant changes we want to focus on in the projections with the LBO as compared to the projections without the LBO: First, interest expense increases (from $1.2 million in 1978 to $41.6 million in 1980) due to the additional debt. Second, depreciation and amortization expense increases due to the write-up of the assets to their purchase price by the LBO. Table 17.6 provides the projected Income Statements with and without the LBO, taken from Appendix 17A (Tables 17A.1 and 17A.4).

Explaining the Miracle: LBOs and Taxes

Table 17.6 shows that Congoleum’s pro forma net income without an LBO is $51.6 million compared to a pro forma net income with an LBO of $8.2 million. Why such a huge difference? The reasons are that with the LBO:

  1. Income before tax is reduced by the $42.0 million increase in depreciation and amortization caused by the higher asset values after the LBO.
  2. Income before tax is reduced by the $41.6 million additional financing charges from the debt incurred to fund the LBO.

Together these two changes cause the income tax to be reduced by $40.2 million. In finance, these tax savings are often referred to as depreciation tax shields and interest tax shields. Explaining these two tax shields one more time: The pro forma in Table 17.6 shows that the LBO has additional depreciation and amortization expenses of $42 million in 1980 (thus increasing SG&A). At a corporate tax rate of 48%, this translates to a tax savings of $20.2 million.

Similarly, the additional interest expense in 1980 is $41.6 million. At a corporate tax rate of 48%, this translates to a tax savings of $20.0 million.

Taken together, the additional tax shield on depreciation and amortization of $20.2 million and the tax shield on interest of $20.0 million combine to the $40.2 million shown in Table 17.7 for 1980.

Table 17.7 Congoleum’s Change in Tax Expense with LBO versus without LBO

1980 1981 1982 1983 1984
Tax expense without LBO 47.7 52.9 58.7 65.2 72.4
Tax expense with LBO 7.5 14.4 22.9 32.5 43.1
Projected tax savings from LBO 40.2 38.5 35.8 32.7 29.3

Looking forward five years, the savings in taxes with the LBO is projected to be roughly $35.3 million per year (a high of $40.2 in 1980 to a low of $29.3 in 1984), as shown in Table 17.7.

A Theoretical Explanation of Our “Miracle of Modern Finance”

Let us return to capital structure theory for a moment. If you recall, M&M (1958) showed us that the “pie” is fixed and that capital structure determines how we cut the slices and who gets them. M&M (1963) showed us that with taxes, the government also gets a slice of the pie and that therefore taxes reduce the size of the slices available to other stakeholders. By increasing debt, we reduce the size of the slice to the government. Keeping with this analogy, the LBO, by increasing interest and depreciation expense, reduces the size of slice going to the government and increases the slices to the other parties. In Congoleum, the government’s share of the pie is reduced by $40.2 million in 1980, according to our pro formas.

However, and this is key, who gets the $40.2 million that used to go to the government in taxes? It now goes to the debt holders in the form of interest and principal repayment. And who are the debt holders? The banks (partially) and Prudential (principally). But remember, Prudential is also the largest equity holder (owning 66% of the equity). By leveraging up the firm to 87% debt, we have reduced the payments to the government and increased the payments to the debt holders. However, unlike our discussion of capital structure, where the cost of increasing the debt increased the risk,15 the strip financing means that debt holders and equity holders are the same parties, and thus the risk of distress has not increased with the increase in debt.

So, what has the firm accomplished by doing the LBO? For one thing, the firm has created a situation where it will pay roughly $40.2 million less in taxes in 1980. In essence, Congoleum borrowed money from Prudential to buy its stock and is now using the tax savings it gets from having debt to pay Prudential back.

To return to our tongue-in-cheek question above, why did Harpel (the Harvard MBA who started all this) give a chair to Harvard’s Kennedy School of Government instead of Harvard’s Business School, from which he graduated? Perhaps it was in honor of the government tax code, which allowed this modern miracle of finance. (This is pure unsupported speculation on your authors’ part.)

Going Forward

Appendix 17A shows the Pro Forma Income Statements and Balance Sheets for 1980–1984 and how they were generated. (Again, we recommend that the reader take time out at this point to skim Appendix 17A.) From Table 17A.4, we are able to generate Congoleum’s pro forma excess cash flows as shown in Table 17.8.

Table 17.8 Congoleum’s Pro Forma Excess Cash 1980–1984

($000’s) 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984
Earnings before interest and tax 57,346 68,272 80,400 93,862 108,805
EBIT * (1 – tax rate of 48%) 29,820 35,501 41,808 48,808 56,579
Plus depreciation and amortization 41,981 41,981 41,981 41,981 41,981
Less CAPEX 0 0 0 0 0
Plus opening net working capital 31,247 56,185 70,622 86,649 104,437
Less ending net working capital (56,185) (70,622) (86,649) (104,437) (124,183)
Free cash flows to the firm 46,863 63,045 67,762 73,001 78,814

Note that we assume that Congoleum is depreciating the patents and other assets for tax purposes but does not require new CAPEX to maintain those patents and other assets. (As noted in Appendix 17A, CAPEX is assumed to equal the depreciation on the pre-LBO assets, so these don’t change over time and the LBO write- ups decrease over time.) Prior to the LBO, additions to PP&E were $12.7 million in 1978 and $6.7 million in 1977.

Table 17.9, which is derived from Table 17A.5 in Appendix 17A, shows that over the first five years after the LBO, the amount of debt decreases substantially. This assumes the excess cash shown in Table 17.8 is used to pay down debt. In fact, even if the excess cash is held by the firm (i.e., not used to pay down debt), we know that the “actual” debt level is debt minus excess cash.

Table 17.9 Congoleum Pro Forma Capital Structure with the LBO

($000’s) 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984
Debt 328,400 306,710 267,089 219,866 163,967 98,544
Total equity 51,200 55,847 67,924 89,193 120,899 164,087
Debt ratio 86.5% 84.6% 79.7% 71.1% 57.6% 37.5%
Times interest n/a 1.38 1.79 2.46 3.60 5.74

Thus, Congoleum is projected to go from being a firm with 86.5% of debt immediately after the LBO to being a firm with 37.5% debt just five years later. The bottom line is that tax payments that used to go to the government are now going to the capital providers of Congoleum, which are largely the debt holders (i.e., Prudential) but also include the equity holders. After the debt is paid down, the firm looks as though it has the same capital structure as before the LBO, but the ownership has changed to Prudential, the investment banks, and management.

In addition to the dramatic drop in debt, Congoleum’s equity also increases substantially, as shown in Table 17.9. The preferred stock remains at $26.2 million. The common equity increases from the initial $25 million investment to $137.9 million (the cumulative net income minus the cumulative preferred dividends).

LBOs appear to be very complicated (different types of debt, preferred stock, etc.). The underlying reality is not that complicated, but it needs to look very complex. Why? So that it qualifies as debt for tax purposes even though the risk level is quite low. The reality of the financing is that the strips are technically debt, but are really more like equity. This is why the deal is structured with senior debt, subordinated debt, junior debt, preferred stock, and so on. Has the government figured this out and changed regulations to prevent companies from avoiding tax payments in this way? Yes and no. Some rules have been changed; others have not. However, this method was allowed in the Congoleum transaction and many others.

Equity Returns

How much equity did First Boston, Century Capital, and Congoleum’s management invest in Congoleum? They invested a total of $8.5 million in 1979. Prudential invested another $16.5 million of common equity. This is a total common equity investment of $25.0 million. What is this equity expected to be worth at the end of 1984? As seen in the pro forma in Appendix 17A, Table 17A.4, in 1984 the firm is projected to have $46.7 million of net income. In addition, the firm is expected to have paid off almost all its debt, as shown in Table 17A.5, with debt (short-term plus long-term) falling from $306.7 million at the end of 1980 to $98.5 million in 1984.

Assume the current equity holders of Congoleum now decide to go public. How much should they expect to receive for their equity? Let us first consider a P/E multiple. Selling the earnings at a multiple of 1.0 would mean the current common equity holders would almost double their money (going from the $25.0 million invested to $46.7 million). A multiple of 1.0 times earnings is clearly way too low. Using Congoleum’s pre-LBO earnings multiple of 7.3, the firm’s market capitalization (sale price) would be $340.91 million. This is a return of over 1,363%, or an average annual return of 68.5% per year. Now you know why we call this the miracle of modern finance. If the current equity holders (Prudential, Century Capital, etc.) were able to sell Congoleum at the average market multiple of 15.0, the returns would be even more spectacular: a market capitalization of $700.5 million, meaning a total return of over 2,800% or an average annual return of 94.5% per year.

How would Byron and Eddy do? Remember they initially put $4 million (of the $10.1 million they received for the stock options, pocketing the remaining $6 million for other uses) into the firm for a 16% equity share. At an earnings multiple of 7.3, management would receive $54.5 million ($340.9 * 16%) on their $4 million investment, plus the salary and perks they earn from running the firm. How does this compare to the salary of $370,000 Mr. Radaker was getting before the LBO? This is the difference between being rich and sincerely rich. Now we are talking sincerely. We can now also recognize the attraction that LBOs might have to management.

Prudential invested a total of $246.1 million in the strips, of which $16.5 million represented a 66% share of Congoleum’s common equity. In our pro formas, five years later the debt and preferred stock of $229.6 million are repaid in full, and the equity is estimated to be worth $225.0 million ($340.9 * 66%) at a multiple of 7.3, or a total of $454.6 million ($229.6 + $225.0). Thus, Prudential earns 84.7%, or an average annual return of 13.1% on its strip investment, in addition to the annual interest and preferred dividend payments.

A quick summary to this point: Congoleum was the first modern LBO. The key to understanding the value creation in this case is that modern LBOs represent an M&M world with little or no financial distress. In M&M’s theoretical world, if there are taxes but no costs of financial distress, you should maximize the amount of debt. Typically, we don’t want to maximize the amount of debt because of the costs of financial distress. In the Congoleum case, however, the participants figured out a way to finance the firm with equity while calling it debt. They then took the money they would have paid to the government and instead paid themselves (as the debt holders).

Price Paid to Old Stockholders

So now we have to ask: Was $38 a share (the LBO price) a fair price to pay? Remember, it was a 50% premium on the market price at the time. But at $38 a share, Congoleum’s management, the investment bankers, Century Capital, and Prudential all made an enormous amount of money. Did they do this at the expense of the old stockholders? Should they have paid the old stockholders more? Well, the old stockholders got 50% more than the market price at the time.

If the management of a public company buys it from the stockholders, is this self-dealing? Furthermore, can management later be held liable? To prevent liability (or at least defend themselves from the charge of self-dealing), what must management do? They must hire an investment bank. Why? To obtain a fairness opinion.16 Management will be sued regardless (if the LBO works well), but a fairness opinion helps protect management from accusations of self-dealing. To the authors’ knowledge, there has never been a successful lawsuit against management, a board of directors, or investment banks where a fairness opinion was obtained before an LBO.

So where did the Congoleum consortium get the fairness opinion? Lazard Frères, an independent investment bank (independent of First Boston, Prudential, Century Capital, and Congoleum’s management). A summary of Lazard’s fairness opinion is presented in Appendix 17B. What did Lazard use to justify its opinion that the price was fair? Lazard used a variety of multiples to value Congoleum’s three separate divisions. Could you have valued Congoleum’s three separate divisions? By this point in the book, your authors hope your answer is, “Absolutely!” Now, Lazard also had people sitting by the phone waiting to see if another bidder came in with a higher offer.

How much would you charge to provide a fairness opinion? What would your hourly rate be? We’re guessing it is substantially below what Lazard charged, which was $3 million. (Your authors would like to point out at this time that they and other academics are perfectly capable of performing the same analysis as the investment banks, and for less money.)

Now, some people might think that Lazard is being compensated for the liability it assumes and for putting its reputation on the line when providing fairness opinions. However, when an investment bank gives a fairness opinion, it typically requires the firm that requested the opinion to indemnify the investment bank from any liability. This means that if there is a lawsuit against the investment bank and the investment bank loses, it does not have to pay. So much for any liability. What about the value of an investment bank’s reputation? We will leave it to the reader to determine the value of an investment bank’s reputation, but we do not believe that reputational risk is what determines their fees.

Furthermore, contingency fees are common for investment bankers in acquisitions. In this case, per page 12 of the proxy statement, Lazard gets a flat fee of $1 million regardless of whether the deal is consummated or not. Lazard also gets a contingency fee of $2 million if the deal goes through. So if Lazard finds that the deal is not fair, it gets the $1 million flat fee. If Lazard says the deal is fair and then the deal is successful, Lazard gets $3 million. Incentive effects are clearly possible.

An old joke is that if the world really wanted peace in the Middle East, then it should have Goldman Sachs represent one side and Morgan Stanley the other side, with the signing of a peace agreement on a contingency fee basis. The punch line is that the world would have peace by the end of the month.

What Happened Next?

So what actually happened to Congoleum? Congoleum did very well after the LBO. The company continued to operate effectively and took the forecast interest tax-shield and depreciation tax-shield. The firm was profitable, well above the forecast, and debt was paid down rapidly. After five years, the tax shields were greatly reduced because the assets were depreciated and the interest tax shield decreased as the debt was reduced. For many LBOs, this is often the time the firm goes public again. Why? The tax advantages of the LBO have been realized and are no longer as large. Furthermore, as we discussed earlier, even at modest earnings multiples, the returns to the LBO investors are significant.

Congoleum did not go public again. Rather, it did a second LBO in 1984. In the second case, the management team brought in new partners, and Byron and Eddy ended up owning 70% of the equity. Prudential, First Boston, and Century Capital all earned a healthy premium of three times earnings for their participation in the first LBO.

Then what happened? In 1986, the management team decided to sell Congoleum. According to the Wall Street Journal:17

Congoleum Corp. has completed the job of dismantling itself with the sale of Bath Iron Works, but the job now is to figure out what to do with the $850 million in cash. Pondering the problem last week was Eddy G. Nicholson, 48, and Byron C. Radaker, 52, formerly the chiefs of Congoleum. They say they owned or controlled 70% of Congoleum’s common stock.

Basically, Byron and Eddy sold off the company to others in pieces18 and netted $595 million ($850 million * 70%) for themselves.

Postscript: What Happened to LBOs?

What happened to LBOs after Congoleum’s LBO? A couple of things happened. Experience tells us that anytime someone gets a good idea, it will be copied. As a result, more money flows into funds to do these deals (i.e., “more money is chasing deals”). The best deals are picked off first. This means that over time the deals got riskier: the LBO candidates were not as good, their cash flows were not as stable, their management not as competent, and so forth.

In addition, the investment banks got greedy. They decided they wanted to keep more of the profits of the deals for themselves rather than selling the LBOs to institutional investors like Prudential and sharing the bulk of the profits. Independently, the junk bond market developed in the 1980s, providing another source of potential funding for LBOs. This allowed the investment banks to obtain funds in the junk bond market (discussed in Chapter 10) instead of going to insurance companies, and the investment bankers and management were able to retain 100% of the equity. The difference, however, is that they did not use strip financing. The junk bond investors didn’t get part of the equity, and the different tiers of debt were not “stapled” together. It also meant that the cost of the debt rose, since the debt holders didn’t share in the equity upside.

Perhaps most important, the debt and the LBO became far riskier with tiered financing than under the strip financing model. If the firm got into trouble, the debt holders were not the same as the equity holders and thus were more willing to force the firm into bankruptcy.

So what had the investment bankers done? They went from an M&M world with taxes and no financial distress back to one with financial distress. Before this change, sometime around late 1984, there had been almost 180 LBOs, only one of which went bankrupt. (There is an excellent article by Kaplan and Stein that studies and documents this change.19) After 1984, the number of LBOs going bankrupt rose, a clear response to the change in the financing structure.

In addition to the change made by investment bankers, Congress also changed the tax laws to make LBOs less attractive. In particular, as part of the Tax Reform Act of 1986 (enacted October 22, 1986), the General Utilities Act was abolished. This is relevant because the General Utilities Act had allowed firms to write up the assets they purchased to the price they paid for them and then to depreciate them from the new higher basis. The new law made it so that purchased assets could no longer be increased to the purchased value (written up) unless the seller paid taxes on the write-up of the assets.

For example, under the General Utilities Act, an investor could purchase a building (or a firm’s assets) for $100 million, depreciate it down to zero, and then sell it to someone else for its market value. This second investor would then also be allowed to depreciate it from their purchase price to zero (thereby getting a tax advantage as well). This could occur repeatedly. This is no longer allowed. Once an asset has been depreciated, if it is sold, the seller will recapture (must pay tax) on the difference between the purchase price and the depreciated value. This one change took away close to half the tax shields in the Congoleum example and made LBOs less profitable in general.

Performance Incentives of LBOs

The above analysis is not meant to imply that the only advantage to LBOs is the increase in tax shields. Importantly, when the managers are also the stockholders, there is evidence that they do a better job in managing the firm. An academic study by Steve Kaplan shows that performance measures (i.e., increases in operating income, decreases in capital expenditures, and increases in net cash flow) all substantially improve after an LBO.20

Thus LBOs, if properly structured, not only return us to an M&M world with no costs of financial distress, they also return us to a world where the managers are the owners so there are no agency costs.

Summary

  1. What makes a good LBO candidate? The three essential requirements for a good LBO candidate are low debt, good cash flow, and capable management. Why low debt? The firm must have low debt because otherwise it can’t lever up. What are good cash flows? They are large enough to exceed the new required debt payments and stable enough to minimize the risk of not meeting them. Good management is also required to run the firm, by either the current management or by their replacement.

    Although not required, it also helps if the firm’s businesses are separable and can be sold off if things don’t go as planned. In addition, excess cash is always nice. Thus, Congoleum was a perfect LBO candidate.

  2. Returning to the dichotomy of product risk and financial risk in corporate finance: Congoleum is essentially the reverse of what we saw in Massey Ferguson (in Chapter 5). Massey Ferguson had a risky product market and needed safety on the financial side. For an LBO, it is the reverse. An LBO should have a very safe product market side (a very safe BBR) but can add more risk on the financial side. However, as pointed out, an LBO is not really as risky on the financial side as it first appears because much of the debt is really equity masquerading as debt.
  3. Strip financing is key to reducing financial risk in LBOs. Invented by First Boston (for Congoleum), strip financing was designed to be called debt so that the firm could obtain the interest tax shield, but the strips are meant to be held by the same people who hold the equity, an arrangement that reduces the costs of financial distress. Strip financing was key in the Congoleum case because it eliminated the conflict among the claim holders by making the debt holders also the equity holders. It mimics M&M (1963) regarding taxes but has low costs of financial distress (as opposed to no costs of distress in M&M).
  4. Academic research shows that the value from an LBO comes not only from the extra interest and depreciation deductions, but also from a change in management incentives. We are not saying management does not work hard when paid $370,000 per year. However, with the potential payoffs from LBOs, managers might even be willing to move a cot into the office.
  5. When do LBO investors get their return? The big return usually comes when the LBO goes public again. The interest and depreciation tax shields don’t last forever. When they start to disappear, the firm goes public, and the LBO equity holders receive their payoff. This is normally done after a period of about three to five years (so near the end of 1984 for Congoleum). Why three to five years? Because that is when most of the increase in PP&E is written off, the debt levels have gone down, and the cash balances are going up.
  6. Are LBOs the same today as they were at the time of the Congoleum? No. What changed? The answer is a bit nuanced with multiple parts. Change occurs whenever a new profitable business or business model is created. Investors, once they understand the new model (in this case LBOs) and begin to see the early returns, line up to fund more LBOs. The first LBOs, those in the early 1980s, were almost all extremely profitable. Early returns were like gathering low-hanging fruit. The later ones were not as profitable.

    Second, LBO returns, even for good candidates, also went down because there were more bidders. For example, if Congoleum had not been the first LBO, what would have happened when First Boston made the $38 a share bid for the firm? Others would probably come in and bid. A bidding war causes the price to escalate, reducing the return to the winning bidders. In the Congoleum case, no one else bid because no one else understood what an LBO was. (In the proxy statement, Lazard states that they contacted fifteen other potential buyers but none were interested.) First Boston’s new structure was difficult to understand at first. (People didn’t see that it was M&M (1963) without financial distress.)

  7. Another change in the market for LBOs occurred when investment banks stopped financing them with strips (around 1984). Investment bankers started financing the LBOs with tiered financing instead, selling the riskiest tier to the junk bond market. This meant the debt holders were no longer also the equity holders. When the investment banks switched from strip to tiered financing, they also changed how they were compensated. This made the debt more closely resemble the regular debt market, where no one debt holder will spend the time and effort to monitor management. But when banks instituted tiered financing, they increased the risk of financial distress.
  8. In addition to these competitive and structural changes, the regulatory environment also changed. As mentioned earlier, the abolishment of the General Utilities Act eliminated one major source of value in LBOs because the depreciation tax shields are no longer available.
  9. Today there is yet another development in the LBO saga, and that is private equity firms. Today, private equity firms have reapplied much of the original LBO model. These firms raise large pools of funds that they then use to acquire firms and take them private. In this process, the private equity firms provide both the debt and equity financing for the acquisition and thus are able to reduce risk while retaining the interest tax shields. This is the same model as starting your own firm and determining its capital structure by choosing whether to call the money you invest debt or equity. In addition, the private equity firms monitor the management closely, thereby reducing the agency costs. Later, the firms bought by private equities are spun off again, similar to the Congoleum LBO model.

Coming Attractions

Our next case involves the acquisition of Family Dollar by Dollar Tree. This case covers strategy, valuation, and execution, which we will do in four consecutive chapters.

Appendix 17A: Congoleum’s Pro Formas with and without the LBO

The pro forma financial statements in this appendix are generated by your authors taking historical ratios and projecting them forward. This is consistent with the discussion in Chapters 3 and 4 on generating pro formas. There are a number of pro formas generated as follows:

Tables 17A.1 and 17A.2 project Congoleum’s Income Statements and Balance Sheets from 1978 to 1979 and 1980, assuming the LBO did not occur.

Table 17A.1 Congoleum Pro Forma Income Statement for 1979 and 1980 without the LBO

($000’s) 1978 Adjustments 1979 1980
Total revenue 575,830 11%/year 639,171 709,480
Cost of sales 385,851 67% of sales 428,245 475,352
Selling and general expenses 108,648 19% of sales 121,443 134,801
Operating profit 81,331 89,483 99,327
Other income 4,281 removed 0 0
Interest expense 1,266 estimate 1,000 0
Profit before tax 84,346 sub-total 88,483 99,327
Income tax 40,486 48% PBT 42,472 47,677
Net income 43,860 46,011 51,650
Earnings per share 3.58 NI/11,783 3.90 4.38
Dividends per share 0.8 25% NI 0.98 1.10
Stock price year-end 26.13 7.3 * EPS 28.47 31.97

Table 17A.2 Congoleum Pro Forma Balance Sheet for 1979 and 1980 without the LBO

($000’s) 1978 Adjustments 1979 1980
Cash 77,254 plug 85,857 112,642
Receivables 64,482 11% sales 70,309 78,043
Inventory 75,258 13% sales 83,092 92,232
Other current assets 3,511 flat 3,511 3,511
Current assets 220,505 242,769 286,428
PP&E 70,777 flat 70,777 70,777
Goodwill and other 31,770 flat 31,770 31,770
Total assets 323,052 345,316 388,975
Current portion long-term debt 460 paid off
Accounts payable 41,578 7% sales 44,742 49,664
Other current liabilities 68,359 flat 68,359 68,359
Current liabilities 110,397 113,101 118,023
Long-term debt 14,949 paid off
Other long-term liabilities 10,221 flat 10,221 10,221
Total liabilities 135,567 123,322 128,244
Contributed capital 16,256 flat 16,256 16,256
Retained earnings 171,229 +NI – Divd 205,738 244,475
Total equity 187,485 221,994 260,731
Total liabilities and equity 323,052 345,316 388,975

Table 17A.3 projects Congoleum’s Balance Sheet for 1979 and assumes the LBO occurs. In fact, the LBO occurred on January 29, 1980. For simplicity, the impact of the one extra month is ignored in the presentation. Note, the 1979 year-end Income Statement does not change since the LBO happened after the end of the year.

Table 17A.3 Congoleum Pro Forma Balance Sheet before and after the LBO

Without LBO With LBO
($000’s) 12/31/1979 12/31/1979
Cash and marketable securities 85,857 plug (2,343)
Receivables 70,309 no change 70,309
Inventory 83,092 no change 83,092
Other current assets 3,511 no change 3,511
Current assets 242,769 154,569
Net property, plant, and equipment 70,777 + adjustment 71,806 142,583
Intangibles and patents 31,770 + adjustment 174,000 205,770
Total assets 345,316 502,922
Bank debt 0 + bank debt 125,000 125,000
Accounts payable 44,742 no change 44,742
Other current liabilities 68,359 no change 68,359
Current liabilities 113,101 238,101
Long-term debt 0 + new notes 203,400 203,400
Other long-term liabilities 10,221 no change 10,221
Total liabilities 123,322 451,722
Contributed capital 16,256 reset to 51.223 51,200
Retained earnings 205,738 reset to 0 0
Total equity 221,994 51,200
Total liabilities and equity 345,316 502,922

Tables 17A.4 and 17A.5 project Congoleum’s Income Statements and Balance Sheets from 1980 to 1984 assuming the LBO occurs.

Table 17A.4 Congoleum Pro Forma Income Statements after the LBO

($000’s) 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984
Total revenue 709,480 787,523 874,150 970,306 1,077,041
Cost of sales 475,352 527,640 585,681 650,105 721,617
Selling and general expenses 176,782 191,611 208,069 226,339 246,619
Operating profit (EBIT) 57,346 68,272 80,400 93,862 108,805
Interest expense 41,608 38,244 32,697 26,086 18,950
Profit before tax 15,738 30,028 47,703 67,776 89,855
Income tax 7,554 14,414 22,897 32,533 43,130
Net income 8,184 15,614 24,806 35,243 46,725

Table 17A.5 Congoleum Pro Forma Balance Sheets after the LBO

($000’s) 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984
Cash 10,642 11,813 13,112 14,554 16,156
Receivables 78,043 86,627 96,157 106,734 118,474
Inventory 92,232 102,378 113,639 126,140 140,015
Other current assets 3,511 3,511 3,511 3,511 3,511
Current assets 184,428 204,329 226,419 247,939 278,156
Net property plant & equipment 135,402 128,221 121,040 113,859 106,678
Intangibles 170,970 136,170 101,370 66,570 31,770
Total assets 490,800 468,720 448,829 431,368 416,604
Bank debt 103,310 63,689 16,466
Accounts payable 49,663 55,127 61,190 67,922 75,393
Other current liabilities 68,359 68,359 68,359 68,359 68,359
Current liabilities 221,332 187,175 146,015 136,281 143,752
Long-term debt 203,400 203,400 203,400 163,967 98,544
Other long-term liabilities 10,221 10,221 10,221 10,221 10,221
Total liabilities 434,953 400,796 359,636 310,469 252,517
Preferred stock 51,200 51,200 51,200 51,200 51,200
Common equity (CS & R//E)25 4,647 16,724 37,993 69,999 112,887
Total equity 55,847 67,924 89,193 120,899 164,087
Total liabilities and equity 490,800 468,720 448,829 431,368 416,604

Assumptions for Congoleum’s Pro Formas without the LBO (Tables 17A.1 and 17A.2)

  • Sales growth of 11% (the average growth from 1974 to 1978).
  • Cost of sales at 67% (the 1978 level).
  • SG&A at 19% (the 1978 level).
  • Interest expense for 1979 is set slightly below the 1978 amount (reflecting the debt being paid off each year) and is zero in 1979 (as the debt is fully paid off).
  • Tax is 48% of the profit before tax amount.
  • Earnings per share (EPS) is net income divided by 11.783 million shares.
  • Dividends paid are 25% of net income (and dividends per share are total dividends divided by 11.783 million shares).
  • The year-end stock price is 7.3 times EPS.
  • Cash is the plug figure, the amount required to make the Balance Sheet balance.
  • Accounts receivable is set at 11% (the 1978 level).
  • Inventory is set at 13% (the 1978 level).
  • Other current assets, PP&E, and Goodwill are all held constant (at the 1978 amount).
  • Debt is paid off (given the large cash balance).
  • Accounts payable is set at 7% of sales (the 1978 level).
  • Other current liabilities are held constant (at the 1978 level).
  • Other long-term liabilities and contributed capital are held constant (at the 1978 level).
  • Retained earnings are the ending balance from 1978 plus the pro forma net income computed in Table 17A.1, less an assumed dividend of 25% of net income.

Congoleum’s Pro Formas with the LBO

Table 17A.3 (which shows how Congoleum’s Balance Sheet might have appeared in 1979 with the LBO) is generated using the pro forma 1979 Balance Sheet in Table 17A.2 (which shows how Congoleum might have appeared in 1979 without the LBO). Table 17A.3 is then adjusted for the changes due to the LBO (e.g., with changes in value due to the LBO). Note that there is no change in the 1979 Income Statement as the LBO occurs after year-end and thereby has no effect on income until 1980. The key changes are:

  1. The assets are written up after the LBO by $245.8 million, with $174.0 million allocated to patents and the remaining $71.8 million allocated to PP&E. How do we get the $245.8 million amount? It is the difference between the $467.8 million paid to purchase Congoleum (the $447.7 million paid to stockholders plus the $10 million in fees and the $10.1 million paid to the executives) and the $222.0 million net book value of the firm without the LBO in Table 17A.3 (assets of $345.3 million less liabilities of $123.3 million) at the time of the LBO. The $174 million allocated to the patents is based on an estimate provided in Congoleum’s proxy statement.21 For simplicity, PP&E is increased by the remaining $71.8 million. In reality, each individual asset and liability would be adjusted to its market value, with the remainder allocated to goodwill.22

  2. The short-term debt is increased by $125 million, the amount of the new bank debt.
  3. The long-term debt increases, as stated earlier, by the $113.6 million of senior notes plus the $89.8 million in junior notes, or a total of $203.4 million.
    To restate the preceding paragraph: (millions)
    Cash paid for Congoleum (Table 17.3) $467.8
    Pro forma total assets 12/31/1979 $345.3
    Pro forma total liabilities 12/31/1979 $123.3  
    Net book value 12/31/1979  $222.0
    Purchase price discrepancy $245.8
    Allocated to patents (appraisal) $174.0
    Allocated to PP&E $ 71.8 $245.8
  4. The contributed capital is reset, as stated above, to reflect the preferred stock of $26.2 million plus the common stock of $25 million, or a total of $51.2 million.
  5. The retained earnings are reset to $0 after the purchase, as the assets and liabilities have been reset to their purchase price.

Congoleum’s Post LBO Pro Formas 1980–1984 (Tables 17A.4 and 17A.5)

We are now able to generate Congoleum’s pro forma Income Statements and Balance Sheets with the LBO. We will use many of the assumptions in Tables 17A.1 and 17A.2 as well as the changes noted in Table 17A.3.

The pro forma Income Statements (Table 17A.4) are generated using the following assumptions:

  • Sales growth of 11% (the average growth from 1974 to 1978).
  • Cost of sales at 67% (the 1978 level).
  • SG&A at 19% of sales (the 1978 level) plus $41.98 million for the additional depreciation and amortization. For simplicity, PP&E is depreciated evenly over ten years and the patents over five years. Thus:
  • Depreciation and amortization is estimated as follows:

Yearly additionally depreciation on PP&E $ 71.8/10 $ 7.18
Yearly additional amortization on patents $174.0/5 $34.80
Total increase in depreciation and amortization $41.98
  • Interest expense is 14% of the prior year-end bank debt (for 1980 this would be 14% * $125 million = $17.5 million) plus 11.25% on the senior debt (for 1980 this would be 11.25% * $113.6 million = $12.8 million) plus 12.25% on the junior notes (for 1980 this would be $113.6 million at 11.25%) plus $11.0 million on the junior notes (for 1980 this would be 12.25% * $89.8 = $11 million).
  • For simplicity, each year’s interest expense is based on the amount of outstanding debt at the end of the prior year. Excess cash is assumed to be used to pay off debt on the last day of the year. The bank debt is assumed to be paid off first. This is both because it has a higher rate and also because senior debt (in this case, the bank debt) normally has covenants that prevent paying off junior debt first. Once the bank debt is fully paid off, the senior debt is paid off next and the and junior notes are paid off last.24

  • An income tax rate of 48% is used, as it was the corporate tax rate at the time of the LBO. (Students today would use a tax rate closer to the current maximum corporate tax rate of 35%. Students reading this book 30 years in the future . . . you get the idea.)

The pro forma Balance Sheets (Table 17A.5) are generated using the following assumptions:

  • Congoleum maintains a minimum cash balance of 1.5% of sales. Any balance above this amount is considered excess cash and used to pay down debt.
  • Accounts receivable is set at 11% of sales (the 1978 level).
  • Inventory is set at 13% of sales (the 1978 level).
  • Other current assets are held constant (at the 1978 level).
  • PP&E and Intangibles, after being increased by the LBO (as per Table 17A.3), are reduced evenly over 10 years ($7.18 million) and 5 years ($34.8 million) respectively. CAPEX is assumed to match the depreciation on the prior balances (i.e., the change in PP&E and Intangibles is the additional depreciation and amortization on the LBO write-ups only).
  • The bank debt is paid down, as noted above.
  • Accounts payable is set at 7% of sales (the 1978 level).
  • Other current liabilities are held constant (at the 1978 level).
  • The long-term debt is paid down, as noted above.
  • Other long-term liabilities are held constant (at the 1978 level).
  • Contributed capital is assumed to remain constant.
  • Retained earnings are increased by the pro forma net profit and reduced by the preferred stock dividend of $3.542 million (322,000 shares @ $11/share). No other dividends are paid since all excess cash is assumed to pay down debt.

Thus, Tables 17A.1 through 17A.2 help generate Tables 17A.4 and 17A.5. These in turn generate Table 17.8 in the chapter.

Appendix 17B: Highlights of the Lazard Fairness Opinion

January 8, 1980

  • Lazard Frères & Co.
  • One Rockefeller Plaza
  • New York, N.Y. 10020
  • The Board of Directors
  • Congoleum Corporation
  • 777 East Wisconsin Ave.
  • Milwaukee, Wisconsin 53202

Dear Sirs,

In connection with the proposed acquisition of Congoleum Corporation (“Congoleum”) by a group of private investors organized by The First Boston Corporation (“First Boston”), you have requested our opinion on the fairness of the $38 cash per share proposal to be paid to the stockholders of Congoleum. The acquisition will be effected by the sale of substantially all the assets of Congoleum (with the exception of cash and equivalents to be retained by Congoleum as described in the Proxy Statement, as defined below), subject to substantially all the liabilities of Congoleum, to a privately held company formed to acquire Congoleum. The stockholders of Congoleum will be paid a liquidating distribution of $38 per share from the proceeds of the sale and the cash items retained by Congoleum, and Congoleum will be dissolved (all of the foregoing transactions being referred to herein as the “Transactions”).

In arriving at our opinion we have, among other things:

  1. reviewed published materials by and regarding Congoleum, including its annual reports on form 10-K and its interim reports filed with the Securities and Exchange Commission . . .
  2. considered the financial position and operating results of Congoleum for the five years ended December 31, 1978 . . .
  3. reviewed the financial position and operating results for the 9 months ended September 30, 1979 and September 30, 1978, and discussed with management subsequent thereto the key factors affecting Congoleum’s current and prospective results;
  4. visited the major facilities of Congoleum;
  5. reviewed the financial condition and operating results for comparable periods of companies which we consider generally similar to Congoleum or to one of its three basic businesses;
  6. made a valuation of Congoleum’s three basic business units as if they each were “free standing companies,” based on multiples of each unit’s earnings derived from an analysis of each unit’s competitors or companies similar to each unit;
  7. considered the strong recent improvement in Congoleum’s financial condition and operating results;
  8. reviewed and considered Congoleum’s stock price history over the past five years;
  9. reviewed terms of selected recent major acquisition transactions;
  10. reviewed and considered the First Boston proposal and the documents relating to the Transactions presented in the proxy statement; and
  11. reviewed the pro forma capitalization and financial projections of Fibic Corporation for the years 1980 through 1984.

We have assumed, without independent verification, the accuracy and completeness of the information in the Proxy Statement, other publicly available information and information provided to us by Congoleum and Fibic.

Based upon our analysis of the foregoing and upon such other factors as we deem relevant including our assessment of general economic, market and monetary conditions . . . we are of the opinion that the $38 cash per share to be paid as a liquidating distribution is fair to the stockholders of Congoleum from a financial point of view.

  • Yours very truly,
  • Lazard Frères & Co.

In addition to the letter above, the proxy statement notes that (in a memorandum Lazard gave to the Board) Lazard: “explored with fifteen companies that it regarded as prospective buyers the possible purchase of Congoleum and/or any of its major divisions and found that none of them was interested in any such purchase . . . that only one outside source had contacted it expressing possible interest in acquiring Congoleum, but that source did not actively pursue the matter. . . . made a valuation of Congoleum’s three business units as if they were “free standing companies.” Based upon this method of valuation, the range of values of Congoleum as a whole included a low of approximately $430,000,000 ($35 per share) and a high of approximately $479,000,000 ($39 per share), with a mid-point of the derived range being approximately $455,000,000 ($37 per share). These values were before any expenses. . . .”

Notes

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset