CHAPTER 10
The Impact of Operating Strategy on Corporate Finance Policy (MCI)

We begin this chapter with a review of the previous two chapters. This has two purposes: one to reinforce the material for the reader; the other, to allow this chapter to be read on its own. In particular, we are going to review and expand the discussion of asymmetric information and signaling from the earlier chapters. Then we will use MCI to illustrate how a firm’s operating strategy impacts its corporate financial policies.

A Brief Summary

We noted (in Chapters 8 and 9) that the following actions provide signals to the market. When a firm issues equity, its stock price drops on average. When a firm does a tender offer for its own shares, the firm’s stock price rises on average. When a firm initiates a dividend for the first time or raises its current dividend, the stock price goes up. When a firm cuts or eliminates its dividend, the stock price goes down. All of these price reactions are statistically significant.

In the last chapter, we stated that the market’s reaction to these events is due to asymmetric information. The insight behind why asymmetric information matters is that investors believe that managers have more information than they do, so investors therefore watch and react to what management says and does. A secondary insight is that investors don’t know whether what management is saying is credible or not. However, investors do know that if management increases the payout of equity cash flows, then there is probably an excess of cash flows to the firm. (Payouts of equity cash flows are executed with stock repurchases and increased dividend repayments.) Furthermore, if the management raises new equity or decreases equity cash flows, then there is probably a shortage of cash flows. (Raising new equity or decreasing equity cash flows are executed by stock issues and dividend cuts.) Thus, equity cash flows provide information, or signals, to investors. As a consequence, stock price will rise when the firm pays out equity cash flows, since it signals excess cash flows, while the stock price will fall when new equity is issued or when equity cash flows to investors are reduced, since these signal reduced cash flows.

Since investors react to “signals” from the firm, let’s now ask: What makes a good signal? A good signal should be credible and simple to understand and calibrate. In addition, a signal should also be visible—something that all investors will notice. Finally, there should be a penalty for false signaling. Now imagine a CEO speaking before the Society of Security Analysts and saying that the firm is “doing very well.” What does “very well” mean? Suppose the CEO instead says the firm is “doing well.” These statements are not much of a signal. It is very hard to determine the difference between “very well” and “well.”

Cash flow in and out of the firm is almost the perfect signal. First, cash is credible: management is actually paying out or taking in cash. Second, cash is simple to understand and calibrate—investors do not have to interpret the difference between doing “well” versus “very well.” If a firm increases its dividend from $1.00 per share last year to $1.50 this year, it is clear the firm is paying 50% more. Third, cash is visible. Investors might not read the annual report or hear the message from the CEO, but they will notice the firm’s dividend payments and will absolutely “cash the check” (dividends no longer come as physical checks, but we like the imagery). Finally, there is also a real penalty for false signaling. If management misleads investors and is in fact not doing “well” but has increased cash dividends anyway, management must replace that cash somewhere else later.

An analogy: Imagine you attend your class reunion. One former classmate is boasting about how well he has done since leaving school and even offers to show you his audited financial statements. At the same time, another classmate is handing out $1,000 bills in the corner. Which former classmate do you believe is doing better? The one boasting or the one handing out cash? The one handing out cash is more credible. This is an example of signaling.

Now let us put together some of what we have learned so far from the Marriott and AT&T chapters. We know firms are reluctant to issue equity. This fact makes other financial concepts important, for example, sustainable growth. There is power to the concept of sustainable growth if firms are reluctant to issue equity. If a firm cares about its capital structure and how much debt it has, yet is reluctant to issue new equity, then the ability to generate internal equity (which sustainable growth measures) is important. In addition, having cash on hand or lines of credit the firm can draw upon (sometimes called “financial slack”) is important because the firm doesn’t necessarily have to go to the capital markets at what might be an inopportune time. Signaling makes a firm’s internal capital markets and its generation of internal cash flow important.

Signaling and its consequences also give rise to something called the pecking order theory (introduced at the end of Chapter 9). The pecking order theory is predicated on the idea that a firm first looks for funds internally before going to the outside capital market. Furthermore, if a firm raises capital in the outside capital markets, the firm will look to issue debt first and will look to issue equity last. Empirically, we see this result in two ways: First, in the percentage of funds obtained from internal growth versus debt versus equity. Second, in how the market reacts to each kind of financing—remember how the market reacts to equity cash flows in and out of the firm. In addition, there is no market reaction to new debt issues.

Let us list some financial objectives for firms (this is not a complete list, but it is illustrative of the trade-offs that occur in corporate finance):

  1. Do all positive-NPV investments. A firm should undertake any project that has a positive NPV since it increases firm value.
  2. Maintain an optimal debt/equity level. This allows the firm to minimize the cost of capital and maximize the stock price without undertaking excessive risk.
  3. Don’t cut dividends. We will talk more about this in the next chapter, but firms rarely cut dividends for any reason.
  4. Finally, don’t issue equity.

So let’s say you are the CFO of a firm and this is your checklist. The problem is achieving all four simultaneously. There are trade-offs. For example, if the firm has a lot of projects with positive NPVs, but the funding needs for the new projects are greater than the firm’s cash flows from sustainable growth, what should the firm do? If the firm wants to achieve the first objective and accept all positive-NPV projects, then it must do one of the following: issue new debt, issue new equity, or cut dividends. In other words, it must violate one of the other objectives. It is nice to have the four objectives, but they can’t necessarily all be achieved at the same time. This is where the trade-offs come in and where corporate finance becomes fun. If the CFO can achieve all four objectives every year, that is great. The old AT&T did this consistently year after year. Not every firm can do this, however, including the new AT&T.

This ends our review of the prior chapter where we analyzed AT&T, both pre- and postdivestiture (what we called the “old” and “new” AT&T). We looked at the old AT&T’s policies and its funding needs, then we looked at the new AT&T’s policies and its funding needs.

Now we turn to MCI, a competitor of AT&T, and we will follow a parallel structure to Chapter 9. First, we will look at the old MCI and how MCI competed with AT&T before AT&T’s divestiture in January 1984. We will also look at the old MCI’s financial policies and funding needs. Then we will examine the new MCI (after AT&T’s divestiture) and its policies and funding needs. (Your authors think it is useful to use MCI with AT&T to discuss these issues. It allows us to talk about the same financial concepts with two very different firms in the same industry at the same point of time.)

A Brief History of MCI

MCI (originally Microwave Communications, Inc.) was founded in 1963 by John Goeken.1 William McGowan, who later became CEO, joined the firm in 1968. The firm’s initial business plan was to use radio waves and relay stations to transmit point-to-point private phone calls in Illinois and Missouri for trucking companies and other small businesses that wanted to pay less than AT&T’s high long-distance charges. In 1968, MCI decided to expand its microwave relay communication system nationwide. MCI obtained FCC approval for its plan in 1969. In 1980, MCI expanded its service from business customers to residential customers as well. By 1990, MCI was the second-largest telecommunications firm in the United States.

While MCI’s business plan relied on relaying phone calls from relay station to relay station, MCI still required AT&T’s local phone lines for transmitting phone calls to and from the MCI stations. For example, if a MCI customer wanted to make a phone call from Chicago to St. Louis, she would use AT&T (technically Illinois Bell, an AT&T subsidiary) from their office to the Chicago MCI station, and then MCI would transmit the call from Chicago to St. Louis via microwave. The call from MCI’s St. Louis station to the local St. Louis phone number would again be carried on AT&T’s local phone lines. With this plan, the MCI customer only paid for local phone service and avoided AT&T’s long-distance charges.

AT&T fought MCI’s competition by refusing to allow MCI to access AT&T’s local phone lines. This meant that while MCI could transmit communications between its own relay stations, those stations could not receive or send calls that connected MCI’s customers. MCI fought back with numerous lawsuits, including a charge filed in 1974 that accused AT&T of violating the U.S. government’s antitrust laws (a charge the U.S. Justice Department also made in a separate case in November 1974).2

Eventually, the U.S. Justice Department’s lawsuit resulted in the 1982 decision that AT&T had to divest its local phone service (the Baby Bells). The divestiture took place in January 1984.

MCI’s Finances

Tables 10.110.3 provide MCI’s Income Statements, Balance Sheets, and Cash Flow Statements from 1979 to 1983 (i.e., the “old MCI”).3 Notice that the numbers in the MCI statements above are in $ thousands, while the numbers discussed in the last chapter for AT&T were in $ millions.4 We will use the tables to determine MCI’s financial policies and financing needs.

Table 10.1 MCI Income Statements 1979–1983

($000’s) 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983
Sales 95,243 144,345 234,204 506,352 1,073,248
Local interconnection 20,542 32,998 50,242 76,203 172,661
Customer installation and service 8,827 6,951 18,532 47,001 137,221
Operations 4,843 22,360 31,801 48,711 147,190
Sales and marketing 7,549 12,822 27,172 50,743 101,838
Admin and general 10,533 14,880 29,227 60,964 115,470
Depreciation 12,342 17,165 25,892 55,704 103,757
Total operating expenses 64,636 107,176 182,866 339,326 778,137
Income from operations 30,607 37,169 51,338 167,026 295,111
Interest expense 23,366 24,132 27,361 53,364 75,322
Other income (expense) (165) 308 (454) 15,640 20,802
Profit before tax 7,076 13,345 23,523 129,302 240,591
Income tax 3,541 6,220 4,781 42,581 69,811
Profit after tax 3,535 7,125 18,742 86,721 170,780
Tax loss carry forward 3,541 6,220 2,372
Net profit (loss) 7,076 13,345 21,114 86,721 170,780
Times interest (EBIT/I) 1.30 1.55 1.86 3.13 3.92
Sales growth 28.6% 51.6% 62.3% 116.2% 112.0%

Table 10.2 MCI Balance Sheets (March 31) 1979–1983

($000’s) 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983
Cash 10,277 7,867 12,697 144,487 541,991
Accounts receivable 6,466 13,550 32,435 78,491 161,607
Other current assets 1,026 2,535 3,814 5,450 9,566
Total current assets 17,769 23,952 48,946 228,428 713,164
PP&E net 188,948 281,990 409,980 619,485 1,324,166
Other assets 2,755 3,901 7,966 12,485 33,137
Total assets 209,472 309,843 466,892 860,398 2,070,467
Long-term debt—current 25,822 31,619 39,921 40,325 48,038
Accounts payable 13,297 22,280 31,030 119,875 202,653
Advances and other 5,564 4,245 2,778 25,340 70,728
Total current liabilities 44,683 58,144 73,729 185,540 321,419
Long-term debt 153,304 172,852 242,707 400,018 895,891
Other 2,409 34,058 87,525
Total liabilities 197,987 230,996 318,845 619,616 1,304,835
Contributed capital 103,505 165,699 225,242 234,878 588,948
Retained earnings (deficit) (92,020) (86,852) (77,195) 5,904 176,684
Total shareholders’ equity 11,485 78,847 148,047 240,782 765,632
Total liabilities and equity 209,472 309,843 466,892 860,398 2,070,467
Debt ratio (D/(D + E)) 94.0% 72.2% 65.6% 64.6% 55.2%

Table 10.3 MCI Cash Flows (March 31) 1979–1983

($000’s) 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983
Net income 7,076 13,345 21,114 86,721 170,780
Depreciation 12,342 17,165 25,892 55,704 103,757
Change in working capital (381) 1,481 (17,711) (68,075) (356,570)
Cash from operations 19,037 31,991 29,295 74,350 (82,033)
Capital expenditures 52,502 110,252 155,654 271,464 623,010
Preferred stock dividends 3,352 11,457
Funds required 52,502 110,252 155,654 274,816 634,467
Net financing required 33,465 78,261 126,359 200,466 716,500
External financing:
Net debt issued 3,963 18,972 77,327 157,466 827,979
New equity issued 35,681 75,755 66,176 148,631 354,070
Total external financing 39,644 94,727 143,503 306,097 1,182,049
Net cash flow 6,179 16,466 17,144 105,631 465,549

What were the old MCI’s financial needs (before the AT&T divestiture)? To determine which financial policies a firm should implement, it is first important to determine its financing needs. So, what were the old MCI’s financial needs? Determining past financing needs can be found using cash flow statements. Predicting future financing needs is done using pro formas exactly as we did it with PIPES in Chapters 2–4. As shown in the middle of Table 10.3, MCI’s net financing requirements by year were:

Year Net Financing Required
1979 $ 33,465,000
1980 $ 78,261,000
1981 $ 126,359,000
1982 $ 200,466,000
1983 $ 716,500,000
For a total of $1,155,051,000

Given MCI’s financing needs, what were its financial policies? In the last chapter we saw that the “old” AT&T had consistent financial policies. This is not true for the “old” MCI. Let’s start with MCI’s debt policy and its target debt rating. Looking at Table 10.2, MCI’s target debt ratio is not obvious. In 1979, MCI had a debt ratio of 94% debt. In 1983, it was 55.2%. MCI’s interest rate coverage, given in Table 10.1 as times interest, improved dramatically (in 1979 it was 1.30 times, while in 1983 it was 3.92 times). Moreover, MCI’s debt was not rated during this time.5

What about MCI’s dividend policy? The old MCI did not pay a common stock dividend (it only paid a small, but required, preferred share dividend in 1982 and 1983). Thus, the dividend policy of the old MCI was not to pay any common stock dividends. This reflects the fact that MCI has too many financing needs and is not generating much cash flow.

What about a debt maturity policy: Should it be long or short? Fixed or floating? It is not clear from MCI’s financing decisions. The financial exhibits indicate that the old MCI really did not have any financial policies. MCI’s financials also didn’t have any consistency. The old AT&T’s ratios were the same every year, whereas the old MCI’s ratios bounced all over the place. The old MCI’s level of profit was also widely variable, and its debt was not even rated debt. The firm’s financial policy was basically survival: get money any way you can to survive and live another day.

So how did MCI finance itself? Table 10.3 indicates MCI did both external debt and equity financing. Table 10.4 explicitly shows how MCI financed itself (through March 31, 1983) with two issues of common stock, three issues of convertible preferred issues, three issues of convertible debt issues, and three straight debt issues. (Convertible preferred and convertible debt is preferred stock and debt when it is issued but may be converted into common equity in the future. A more complete discussion of convertibles follows shortly.) MCI eventually converted all of its convertible preferred stock and two of its convertible debts issued between March 1980 and December 1982. What did this do to the old MCI’s debt ratio? Converting the stock and debt issues to common equity reduced the debt ratio greatly because a lot of the debt on MCI’s Balance Sheet became equity.

Table 10.4 Selected MCI’s External Financings 1978–19837

Date Security Details ($ Millions) Proceeds (Net of Underwriting Fees)
06/72 Common Stock 3.3 million shares at $10.00 a share 30.2
11/75 Unit of Common Stock and Warrants 1.12 million units of 4 shares and 4 warrants (conversion 1 warrant to 1 share at $2.50) 8.5
12/78 Convertible Cumulative Preferred Stock 1.2 million shares of 2.64% at $25/share (conversion at $0.547/common share) 28.6
09/79 Senior Convertible Preferred Stock 4.95 million shares of $1.80 at $15/share (conversion at $1.25/common share) 69.5
07/80 Subordinated Debentures $52.5 million, 15%, due 8/01/00 50.5
10/80 Convertible Cumulative Preferred Stock 3.63 million shares of $1.84 at $15/share (conversion at $2.25/common share) 51.4
04/81 Subordinated Debentures $125 million, 14.125%, due 4/01/01 (issued at 84.71% of par) 102.1
08/81 Convertible Subordinated Debentures $100 million, 10.25%, due 8/15/01 (conversion at $3.21/common share) 98.2
05/82 Convertible Subordinated Debentures $250 million, 10%, due 5/15/02 (conversion at $5.625/common share) 246.0
09/82 Subordinate Debentures $250 million, 12.875%, due 10/01/02 (issued at 85.62% of par) 214.0
03/83 Convertible Subordinated Debentures $400 million, 7.75%, due 3/15/03 (conversion at $13.03/common share) 394.0

Common Equity

When MCI got approval from the FTC to compete with AT&T in 1972, MCI went public and raised funds with an IPO (an Initial Public Offering of equity). The firm issued 3.3 million shares at $10.00 a share for a total of $33 million (the net after banking fees was $30.2 million).6 It also obtained a bank line of credit for $64 million at 3.75% above prime, plus a 0.5% commitment fee. This means MCI was paying 425 basis points (3.75% plus 0.5%) above prime for its debt.

In 1975, MCI went back to the equity market selling stock in a unit deal for $0.85 per share. What is a unit deal? It is an offering of more than one security linked together. The securities can be either detachable or undetachable. Basically, MCI offered a unit of common stock plus a warrant. For $0.85, an investor received one share of stock and a warrant (meaning a right) to buy another share of stock at a price of $2.50 at some time in the future, up to five years from the initial sale. This was a two-for-one deal created for MCI by the investment banking firm Drexel Burnham Lambert, which no longer exists. Note that shareholders had previously paid $10.00 for a share during MCI’s 1972 IPO, and now for $0.85 the firm was offering a share plus a warrant to buy another share.

A warrant is an option that the firm issues. The holder of the warrant has the ability to “exercise” the warrant, which involves turning in the warrant plus cash and receiving equity. Just like an option, the warrant has an expiration date after which it becomes worthless. Unlike an option, warrants are often callable which means the firm can force the holder to either exercise the option or have it expire at a call date.

Convertible Preferred Stock and Convertible Bonds

As shown in Table 10.4, MCI issued many convertibles, both convertible bonds and convertible preferred stock. What is a convertible? It is a bond or preferred stock that gives its holders an option to convert into stock. For ease, let’s just discuss bonds (convertible preferred shares work similarly). A convertible bond is basically a straight bond with an equity option. How does it work? The bond has a conversion ratio and a conversion price. Let us say a firm issues a $1,000 bond that converts into 20 shares. What is the conversion price? $50, which we calculate by taking the face price of the bond ($1,000) and dividing by the number of shares the bond converts into. Alternatively, if you have the bond’s issue price and conversion price, you can find the number of shares it will convert into: for example, a $1,000 bond divided by a conversion price of $50 is 20 shares. Typically a firm will issue a bond so the conversion price is 15–20% above the current market price of the shares. In other words, the conversion option is “out of the money.”

Will the coupon on a convertible bond be above or below that on straight debt? Below. Why? The firm is giving the buyer an equity option, which has value, and in return pays a lower coupon rate. On straight debt, the buyer only gets the coupon value and has no upside in the stock price. With a convertible, if the stock price goes up enough, the bondholder will receive a portion of the gain. This is why the buyer of a convertible will accept a lower coupon. In addition, the more valuable the option, the lower the coupon.

What price will a convertible bond trade at? A convertible bond is valued as the maximum of either the underlying straight bond or the value of the converted equity. It will trade at close to its bond value as long as its conversion value remains out of the money. That is, it will trade at the present value of the coupons discounted by the market interest rate (plus a small premium for the out-of-the-money equity option). Once the conversion option is in the money, however, then the bond will trade close to the value of the converted shares. That is, it will trade at close to the stock price times the conversion ratio (plus a small premium for the put value, as explained below).

As an example, imagine a $1,000 bond with a conversion ratio of 20 and a conversion price of $50. Now assume the price of the stock is $60. The conversion value of this bond, if it converts into 20 shares, is $1,200. Therefore, if you own this bond, you are never going to sell the bond for less than $1,200 because you could get $1,200 for the shares you can convert it into. Actually, the bond may sell for a bit more than $1,200 because it is actually more valuable than 20 shares of stock. Why? Because the bond has protection on the downside. If you owned 20 shares of stock instead of the convertible bond and the stock price were to drop from $60 to $40, the value of your shares would fall from $1,200 to $800. But if you owned the convertible bond, you would still receive the interest and maturity value of the bond, which should be worth more than $800. This is why a convertible bond will trade for at least the maximum price of the equivalent straight bond or the value of the converted equity.

Let’s ask a new question: If the stock price goes up to $60, should you convert the bond? What is more valuable: 20 shares of the stock at $60, or a bond that converts into 20 shares? The bond. As explained above, the convertible bond is worth more than the stock because of the put option. This means a smart investor is not going to convert voluntarily because he would be giving away the put option. If an investor wants to get out of the investment, he would not convert the bond to sell the stock: he would simply sell the bond.8

Financial economists have a name for people who convert early. We call them doctors. The stereotype is that they are investors who have money to invest but no clue about what they are doing financially. Anyone who converts early is extinguishing a valuable option. So if investors do not convert voluntarily, how does a firm, like MCI, get rid of its convertibles? Convertibles are callable, and the company calls them to force conversion. When a convertible is called, an investor must decide to either convert the bond into stock or receive $1,000 par value in cash from the firm. This means, if the stock price is at $60 per share with a conversion ratio into 20 shares, then the investor can convert his 20 shares into $1,200 of stock or receive $1,000 in cash. Normally investors have a 30- or 60-day period to make the decision, and at the end of the period, they have to inform the firm of their choice. Now what should the investor do? Convert: $1,200 worth of stock is more valuable than $1,000 in cash.

As an aside, perhaps surprisingly, typically only about 98% of investors convert when a firm calls a convertible. There are 1% to 2% of investors who will take the $1,000 in cash rather than take the $1,200 in stock.9 (We want to get a mailing list of those people because we have all sorts of things to sell them.)

Now, why did the old MCI issue convertibles? Why didn’t the firm simply issue straight equity? The reason was that, as we have seen, if MCI issued straight equity, its stock price would have fallen. What about issuing convertibles? Do firms’ stock prices fall when firms issue convertibles? Yes, but not by as much, as we will explain below.10

Should the old AT&T have issued convertibles? We argue no. Why not? Consider the coupon rates AT&T would have gotten on a convertible compared to its coupon on straight debt. We mentioned above that the coupon on convertible debt is typically below the coupon on straight debt because of the convertible’s option value. How much below depends on the value of the option. The greater the potential upside of the stock price, the greater the value of the option and thus the larger the discount on the coupon.

As an example, consider a stock that is worth $30 today and that investors expect to be worth $30 tomorrow and $30 forever (paying a dividend but remaining at a $30 price). Assume this firm can issue 10-year straight debt at a coupon rate of 10%. What coupon rate would you expect it would obtain on a 10-year convertible debt? The same 10% rate. Why? Because there is no option value on the stock since the stock price is expected to remain at $30 (note that this is an exaggerated example used to make a point). Remember, the reason MCI was able to obtain a lower coupon rate by issuing a convertible was because of the high option value of MCI’s stock.

So, what kind of firms issue convertibles? Start-ups, and/or firms with high tech or high R&D, as well as firms with volatile cash flows. In other words, firms with large option values (i.e., firms whose stock prices may rise significantly) and firms for which high fixed-interest expenses may be problematic. AT&T, for example, should not issue convertibles. Why? Because the market did not think there was very much upside to its stock price. AT&T’s stock price was $68.50 a share at the end of 1983, a 17-year high. Furthermore, AT&T had a low interest rate on its straight debt, and it had adequate, stable cash flows to service its debt. Thus, AT&T would not get much of a reduction in interest rates for issuing convertible debt, yet would give away any potential upside in stock price.

Convertible debt was attractive to MCI, because its high option value meant it would obtain a much lower interest rate. The cash flow savings from the lower interest rate were important to MCI since its forecasted cash flows were volatile. In 1982 MCI paid a 14.5% coupon on straight debt, yet only 10% on convertible debt.11 The reader should remain aware, however, that when MCI issued convertible debt, it was potentially giving away the firm’s stock prices’ upside in exchange for a lower interest rate. This meant, if stock prices rose enough, MCI would ultimately be issuing equity at a low price via convertible debt.

Our next question: Why does a firm’s stock price fall less when it issues convertible debt than when it issues equity? As discussed earlier, the stock market seems to interpret an equity issue as meaning the firm has uncertain opportunities or insufficient equity cash flows. If the firm issues convertibles, the market is still troubled but less so. Empirical research shows there is an approximately 3% decline in stock price for an equity issue of about 10% of a firm’s capital and a 1% decline for a convertible debt issue of the same amount.12

An intuitive explanation of why the market interprets convertible issues less negatively than equity issues is as follows: If a firm is certain that future cash flows will be sufficient to pay back a debt issue (i.e., there is no risk of default), and the firm expects its stock price will rise, it should issue debt and not give away the equity upside to new investors. However, if the firm is uncertain whether future cash flows will be sufficient to pay back a debt issue, then the firm will probably issue equity. In doing so, the firm avoids the risk of default, but it does send a negative signal.

Convertible issues send a negative signal but a smaller one than equity issues. A reason the signal is smaller is that if stock prices don’t increase enough to force conversion, convertibles remain debt, which has to be serviced and repaid. Another way to understand this is that if management misleads the market when issuing equity, there are no cash flow consequences to the firm. However, if management issues convertible debt, which doesn’t convert, the firm will still have the debt and have to pay it off. Unconverted convertibles essentially become straight debt. A firm has to make its interest payments or put itself at risk. Thus, convertible debt is a middle ground between straight debt and equity.

Finally, a last way to look at this signal is that when a firm issues equity, the market interprets this as management thinking that the stock price is at a relative high or management anticipating that things are not going to be as good in the future. Issuing convertible debt with the hope that it will convert in the future indicates that management believes the stock price will rise.

To simplify: Those firms with positive NPV projects and lots of positive cash flows will finance with straight debt. Better firms, with positive opportunities but volatile or limited cash flows, will issue convertible debt. Finally, firms with uncertain opportunities and cash flows will issue equity (if they issue debt, even if it is convertible, and things don’t go well they are saddled with a high probability of financial distress).

Interest Rates and Debt Ratios

What were MCI’s interest rates on the straight debt issues? In Table 10.4 the stated coupon rate on straight debt is not the actual interest rate paid. This is because these debt issues were original issue discount (OID) bonds.13 Let’s take the April 1981 debt issue as an example. Since this was an OID bond, MCI did not sell the bond at par value but in fact sold it at substantially below par: at 84.71% of par. Thus, MCI received only $847.10 for each $1,000 par value bond. However, this debt issue had a stated coupon rate of 14.125% on the $1,000 par value, or $141.25 per bond. This means the real interest rate MCI was paying was much higher than the stated 14.125%. MCI’s actual interest rate on this debt was 16.8%.14

What is MCI’s debt ratio? After all this financing activity, MCI’s debt level at the end of 1983 was $943.9 million with total capital of $1,709.5 million ($943.9 million of debt plus $765.6 million of equity) for an apparent debt ratio of 55.2%. However, MCI also had $500 million in cash from its latest round of financing (the total cash balance was $542.0 million, so MCI had $42.0 million of cash on hand prior to the financing). This presumably means that the $500 million of cash from financing is excess cash. As you may recall, excess cash is the same as negative debt. (The previous point is in bold because it is an essential point in corporate finance and one often missed by both students and practitioners.)

This means MCI effectively had $443.9 million of debt ($943.9 million of debt less the $500 million of excess cash) and total capital of $1,209.5 million ($443.9 million of effective debt plus $765.6 million of equity) for a debt ratio of 36.7%. Essentially, this was the debt ratio the instant before MCI issued the new $500 million of debt. Had MCI never issued the additional debt, the firm would have only had $443.9 million of debt with $765.6 million of equity producing a debt ratio of 36.7%.

The fact that MCI issued $500 million of debt and kept it in cash did not really change the firms’ debt ratio because MCI could have used the cash to pay down part of its debt. If a firm uses excess cash to acquire other assets, then all its debt is included in the firm’s debt ratio. The bottom line is that, at the end of 1983 MCI’s actual debt ratio (after taking in account excess cash) was 36.7%.

Leases

MCI also did lease financing. What is lease financing? With a lease, a firm requiring a particular asset for its business essentially rents the asset long term from another firm. This happens in one of two ways: First, an outside firm may already own the asset and lease it to the firm that needs to use it. Second, the firm that needs to use the asset can buy the asset themselves and then sell it to an outside firm while signing a lease contract to use it. Why would a firm buy an asset, sell it to another firm, and then sign a lease to use the asset it just sold? Why wouldn’t the firm just buy the asset themselves to use it? And why would the lessor firm sign up for this? The advantage to the firm leasing the asset (e.g., MCI) is that they get to use the asset without having to finance the cost—it is similar to renting rather than owning a house. The advantage to the firm owning the asset is that they collect the lease payments and also are able to use the tax shield from depreciating the asset.

Doesn’t MCI care about the tax shield? Only recently. MCI’s first year of profitable operations was in 1977 (after suffering over $100 million in losses in its first 14 years of operations). This means MCI did not have taxable profits and would thus not have benefitted from a depreciation tax shield. Even until 1980, MCI was using its past tax loss carryforwards.15 In addition to the tax consequences, MCI did not have enough cash flows or debt capacity to fund all its required capital expenditures. By using leasing, MCI only had to fund the annual lease costs.

Financing Needs of the New MCI

Let us now turn to the financing requirements for the “new” (post AT&T’s divestiture) MCI in January 1984. To do this, pro forma financial statements must be prepared. (As with AT&T, since this chapter is about the consistency between operating and financial policies, rather than about pro formas, we relegate the details of how the pro formas are done, and the Income Statements and Balance Sheets, to Appendix 10, and Tables 10A.1 10A.2, and 10A.3.

The two key elements in estimating MCI’s pro formas are MCI’s sales growth and its sales-to-asset ratio. That is, how fast MCI is going to grow and how much in capital expenditures (CAPEX) they are going to need to build a network to support the growth. As can be seen in Table 10.1, MCI’s sales growth averaged a very high 74% over the 1979–1983 period (28.6%, 51.6%, 62.3%, 116.2%, and 112.0% respectively) while its total assets grew at an average rate of 70.7% (29.9%, 47.9%, 50.7%, 84.3%, and 140.6% from 1979–1983 respectively) as MCI built its network.

This high rate of sales growth is clearly not sustainable. At the beginning of 1984, MCI’s sales growth is coming from two sources: first, the growth in its overall long-distance revenue (which is growing at 15% a year during this period).16 This provided a minimum growth rate for MCI if its market share stayed the same. The second source of growth for MCI is from capturing some of AT&T’s market share. (Importantly, MCI is not the only new phone company on the block in January 1984: other firms, including GTE and IBM, are also seeking to capture market share.)

MCI’s high growth in assets should also decrease as MCI’s network gets built up. MCI, initially had falling sales/assets ratios as it built up its infrastructure. Then, once the infrastructure is built and sales expand, the sales/assets should increase. There are firms whose sales/assets remain constant over time (e.g., fast food restaurant chains typically only have their sales expand with new outlets).

To summarize, the two key elements for MCI’s pro formas covering the period after 1984 are the estimated sales growth (which will probably slow down as MCI penetrates the market) and the sales/asset ratio (which should increase with slower future CAPEX and asset growth). Appendix 10A provides the details of your authors’ assumptions for the pro forma Income Statements and Balance Sheets. Table 10.5 presents the pro forma cash flow statements derived from these assumptions.

Table 10.5 MCI’s Pro Forma Cash Flows 1984–1988: Expected Case

($000’s) 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988
Net income 139,473 229,767 281,878 371,182 534,812
Depreciation 174,875 272,753 384,618 459,441 480,567
Change in working capital
Cash from operations 314,348 502,520 666,496 830,623 1,015,379
Capital expenditures 1,024,036 1,381,150 1,513,531 826,994 535,516
Preferred stock dividends
Funds required 1,024,036 1,381,150 1,513,531 826,994 535,516
Net financing required 709,688 878,630 847,035 (3,629) (479,863)

As seen in Table 10.5, MCI is forecast to fund its pro forma financing needs with earnings, depreciation, and outside financing. Earnings are forecast to be $139 million in 1984 and to steadily rise to $535 million in 1988 for a total of $1.56 billion over the five-year period. The depreciation estimates increase from $175 million in 1984 to $481 million in 1988 for a five-year total of $1.81 billion. Thus, the five-year cash flow provided by operations is estimated at $3.37 billion.

The differences between MCI’s pro forma cash flow from operations and the pro forma CAPEX are MCI’s financing requirements. As shown in Table 10.5, MCI’s net financing needs are forecast to be $710 million,17 $879 million, and $847 million in 1984, 1985 and 1986 respectively. In 1987, the financing needs are forecast to be essentially zero (showing a $4 million excess). By 1988, MCI’s financing needs are a negative $480 million. Why? Because as MCI’s capital expenditures needs go down (as MCI’s initial network is complete) and the firm’s profits go up, it becomes able to internally fund its capital requirements.18 Thus MCI’s cumulative financing needs are approximately $2.44 billion from 1984 through 1986 before its product market strategy matured and net financing was reduced to below zero.

Why is there this pattern of rising and then falling net financing requirements? MCI’s income rises throughout the five years. At the same time, its capital expenditures rise and then fall.

Note: As seen in Appendix 10A, increases in working capital are assumed to net out to zero throughout this time period. The argument is that MCI has virtually no inventory needs, and its low receivables will be balanced against its payables.

Now let’s remember something important here: The preceding is MCI’s expected scenario. Just as we did in the AT&T chapter, we also have to ask: What is the worst-case scenario for MCI? For AT&T, we assumed profits would fall near zero but that the firm would still survive. For MCI, we really have two potentially worst-case scenarios. In the first, profits go to zero, which means MCI will require an extra $1.56 billion in financing over the next five years (i.e., earnings will be reduced by that much). This means that MCI will require approximately $4.00 billion of financing (for 1984–1987), slightly more than 50% above the estimated $2.44 billion in the base-case forecast in Table 10.5. Thus if MCI has no profits, it will need more cash to stay alive.

However, there is another worst-case financing scenario for MCI. MCI will need more cash if MCI grows faster than expected! At the end of March 1983, MCI had approximately 3% of AT&T’s long-distance revenue. In Appendix 10A’s pro formas, we assume that the market grows at 8% each year, that MCI’s market share grows to 10.8% by the end of 1988, and that the sales/PP&E ratio increases from 80.0% in 1984 to 117.6% in 1988. Now suppose the market grows faster than 8% and/or MCI captures a larger share of the market and/or the sale/PP&E ratio does not increase as rapidly. What are MCI’s capital expenditures needs in this situation? Much higher. This revisits what we learned in Chapter 3. The faster a firm grows, the more working capital and CAPEX it requires, and thus the more financing the firm needs.

Let’s briefly review this concept. Using the pro formas in Table 10.5, we project out an expected case that requires MCI to raise $2.44 billion of financing over the next three years. In the last two years, MCI is expected to have excess cash and can pay down debt. MCI’s financing needs could be higher than forecast for two plausible reasons. One, if MCI’s profits are not as high as forecast. Two, if MCI is more successful than forecast (i.e., takes more market share), it will have to build a bigger network and finance more lines, more substations, and so on.

Where Does MCI Go Next?

In the previous section, we generated MCI’s expected financing needs. This is an important, but often overlooked, step in determining capital structure. In this section, we want to examine what MCI should do financially post the AT&T divestiture. We begin with MCI’s competitive situation. More specifically, let’s look at the BBR, the Basic Business Risk, in 1983. BBR is a term your authors use: it is used elsewhere, but it is not standard terminology. Every firm faces both financial risk and competitive or industry risk. We call the industry or competitive risk BBR.

How did MCI compete with AT&T before 1984? The quick answer is that initially MCI was not allowed to fully compete. AT&T was required to allow MCI to use its access lines, and AT&T had regulated rates that it was not allowed to decrease. What was MCI’s competitive advantage over AT&T before the divestiture? Lower rates. How did the competition go so far? In 1983 MCI had over $1 billion in revenues, four years earlier (in 1979) it had under $100 million. In 1983 MCI had a net worth of $766 million and $500 million in excess cash, four years earlier it had a net worth of $12 million.

Now, while MCI had lower rates, it also had lower service quality. Today, for a long-distance phone call, a consumer simply dials 1 and is connected to her long-distance carrier. Back in the late 1980s, however, if a consumer picked up her phone and dialed 1, she automatically got AT&T. If a consumer wanted MCI (and its lower rates), she had to dial 1 and then a 10-digit access code and then the phone number she wanted to call. So if a consumer used AT&T, she dialed 11 digits. If she wanted to use MCI, she would have to dial 21 digits. Furthermore, AT&T routed MCI’s calls on their oldest lines, the ones with the most static. This meant that when using MCI, consumers had a lower cost, but they also had a lower-quality phone call, and they had to dial more digits. Furthermore, the consumer had to do this every time, not just for the first call. At that time, a consumer could not make the extra digits permanent (this changed with programmable phones, but initially all phones were from Western Electric, an AT&T subsidiary, and were not programmable).

With the 1984 divestiture by AT&T of its local operating companies, MCI won the right to dial-1 access (reducing the number of digits to that of AT&T). However, AT&T won the right to compete on price.

Let’s now consider MCI’s business situation post divestiture. What does the industry look like at the start of 1984? There are now five main competitors: AT&T, IT&T, IBM, GTE, and MCI as other firms entered the telecommunications market that MCI opened up. How does MCI compare to everyone else? Though everyone has the same number of initials, MCI is much smaller. In fact, MCI’s Income Statements can potentially get lost in the rounding errors of AT&T. All of MCI’s competitors have financial statements with numbers in the $ millions, while MCI’s financial statements are in the $ thousands. MCI’s capital expenditure in 1983 was $623 million, while AT&T’s CAPEX in 1983 was $7.0 billion. Thus, after the divestiture MCI is competing with giants: IBM, ITT, GTE, and AT&T.

What competitive advantage does MCI have now? Not only is MCI much smaller than all its competitors, it has lost its price advantage. In addition, MCI is also not diversified, as it is in only one business. In contrast, GTE has multiple business lines, IBM has numerous divisions, and AT&T makes phones through Western Electric. So what? MCI may be small, but it is also scrappy. MCI grew up with nothing and had nothing its entire life. The main argument we can make for MCI is that it is focused and accustomed to competition, whereas AT&T is not.

So what is MCI worried about? What are MCI’s main risks going forward? One risk is that AT&T will lower its prices. Will they? It is unclear. It can be argued AT&T wouldn’t lower prices because it would rather keep higher prices on its 70% of the market than lower its prices and compete for all of it. Alternatively, it can be argued that AT&T would lower its prices to drive MCI out of the business. Exactly what AT&T will do is uncertain in 1984.

Another big risk for MCI is technological risk. In 1983 this potentially comes from fiber optics, microwaves, and satellites. (What eventually challenged MCI’s business plan most was none of the above: it was cell phones. So while there is always risk, it is not always necessarily foreseeable.)

Let’s ask a different question: Is this a risky industry? Not overall. Telecommunications is fairly stable. People during a recession don’t say, “I can’t call you until the recovery.” Phone calls are considered necessary by both businesses and consumers. So as an industry, telecommunication is a stable, low-risk business. At the firm level, however, it may be very volatile going forward. Instead of a single monopoly, after 1983 there were four or five major companies all competing. Looking forward ten years, will the players be the same? Probably not. Name one expected survivor? AT&T. Will MCI be one of the survivors? It is not clear. Even though this is a stable industry in aggregate, it is not a stable industry as far as the competitive structure.

Thus the major risk for MCI is that it now has to win/maintain market share without a price advantage. In fact, when the FCC unanimously decided in mid-1985 that it was unfair for dial-1 service to be available only to AT&T’s customers, the government also mandated that all consumers had to choose a long-distance carrier to provide them with dial-1 access. This was done through a series of sequential “regional elections” where ballots were mailed to consumers who could then choose the carrier they wanted.

And what do most people do when there is an election? They don’t bother to vote, and they didn’t in this election either. Since most people did not explicitly choose a carrier, the local phone companies (now divested from AT&T but tied to AT&T for many years) assigned AT&T as those customers’ long-distance carrier by default.19

To challenge this practice, MCI went back to court and argued that customers who didn’t vote should not be automatically assigned to AT&T. The court agreed and ruled that while customers could not be forced to vote, those customers who didn’t vote would have their long-distance carrier randomly assigned to them in the same proportion as the customers who did vote. Thus the new rule allocated the nonvoters based on the choices of those who did vote.

In the end, only about 10% of customers voted. Before the court ruling, the other 90% would have been given to AT&T by the local phone companies. After the court ruling, the other 90% were allocated based on the choices of the 10%. (Note that this means that each customer who voted was essentially counted 10 times.)

So during 198620 MCI has to participate in multiple elections around the country. And how do you win elections? The old-fashioned way: you buy them. This means you advertise extensively. And if you think phone carrier advertising is ubiquitous today, it was significantly more prevalent back then. If you were in the part of the United States currently holding an election, there were AT&T and MCI commercials on all the time. What does this mean for MCI? Marketing expenditures went up dramatically.

Let’s review: We know old MCI’s financing needs. We also know old MCI’s financial policies, which we can summarize in one word: survive. And that’s exactly what they did. We have now also forecast new MCI’s pro forma financial needs for an expected case and a worst case. We have also considered its BBR. So now we are ready and need to develop the new MCI’s financial policies.

What policies make sense now that MCI is larger and profitable, but operates in a highly competitive industry without a price advantage?

Let’s start with the debt ratio. What should MCI’s debt ratio be going forward? In December 1983, MCI’s debt ratio is 36.7% (adjusted for excess cash), while AT&T’s is at 40% to 45%. Should MCI’s be lower? Higher? From Table 10.5, we know MCI will require more financing for at least the next three years. We also know that if MCI increases its debt ratio, it will have less flexibility and more risk. It does not seem like it should, but let’s look at some simpler questions first, and we’ll come back to this one later.

What should MCI’s dividend policy be? Zero (like the past)? Consider the following: MCI has 117 million shares outstanding. In 1983, the firm’s EPS was $1.69 a share. If MCI has a 50% payout—basically $0.85 a share—this translates to about $100 million a year. Thus, over five years, MCI would be paying out about half a billion dollars in dividends. So if MCI has a 50% dividend payout (and earnings stay constant or rise), the firm must raise at least another half billion dollars of outside financing in the next five years.

This demonstrates that financing and dividend policy are connected. A firm cannot just set a dividend policy in isolation. If MCI sets a dividend policy of a 50% payout, this means the firm must raise another half billion dollars in outside financing. Additionally, the level of dividends a firm sets is expected by investors to continue. So, if management sends a false signal (that is, if the firm says it will pay a dividend that it can’t in fact sustain because the firm does not have the future cash flows), then eventually the firm must either cut future dividends or increase outside financing. (We will have much more to say about dividend policy in the next chapter.)

So, what should MCI’s dividend policy be now? Zero! At least until MCI starts generating excess cash flows.

Should MCI’s debt maturities be long or short term? Long. How long? At least past 1987. Why? As we see from the pro formas, that is when MCI will no longer need new financing and will start to generate excess cash. The last thing MCI wants to do is refinance before 1988 while they still need new funding. For example, commercial paper is cheaper (has lower interest rates) than long-term debt (at this time), but it also has to be turned over (refinanced) at least every 270 days. What happens to MCI if it has to refinance and can’t? The firm would be in trouble, and MCI can’t afford that. Instead of having to raise the same funds two or three times, MCI has to make sure the maturity of its debt extends beyond the period when the firm requires the funds.

This is an important point that is often misstated and misunderstood. Essentially, a firm should match the maturity of its financing strategy to the maturity of its product market strategy. Your co-authors have often heard it argued that if the assets are long term, then the liabilities should also be long term. This is incorrect, as we discussed in Chapter 7 about Marriott. While financing long-term assets with long-term liabilities may be correct, it is not how the financing should be decided. If the product market strategy is long term, then the financing strategy should be long term. If the firm is going to need money for at least five years, then the firm may not want to do any financing for less than five years. MCI does not want to have to refinance and raise that money two or three times. Should MCI go out 20 years? The firm doesn’t really need to. MCI should go out at least 10 years if it believes its projections and 20 years only if it is lower-cost financing.

Should the interest on the debt be fixed or floating? Fixed. Why? All of MCI’s competitors have fixed-rate debt, and it is a time of high inflation and interest rates. If inflation and interest rates suddenly increase further, MCI does not want to face a situation in which the firm’s costs increase relative to its competitors (remember what happened to Massey Ferguson in Chapter 5). If all of MCI’s competitors are financed at fixed rates, MCI should not run the risk of having its interest rates increase by using floating-rate financing.

Should MCI prefund, that is, obtain financing ahead of its needs? Perhaps. What would MCI do with the excess funds? Invest it. The firm needs funds over the next five years; exactly when it gets the funds is not as important as whether it gets the funds.

So now we have some indications of what some of MCI’s financial policies should be. Dividend policy set at zero. Debt maturities of at least five years and probably longer. Debt issued with fixed interest rates. And MCI should consider prefunding. However, we still need to discuss MCI’s debt ratio further. That is, should MCI issue debt, equity, or convertibles?

Examining Alternative Financing Choices

So let us come back to our original question: What type of financing should MCI issue? This relates to the question of what MCI’s debt ratio should be.

We know the following: MCI is forecasting CAPEX in 1984 to be $1.3 billion. The firm has $500 million in excess cash (from funds it just raised) and is expected to require over $2 billion in financing over the next three years. Hypothetically, suppose MCI asks its banker, Drexel Burnham Lambert (Drexel), what its financing options are. Their reply is that MCI can potentially finance in several different ways. The firm can issue straight debt, convertible debt, equity, or some combination thereof. The amounts and costs of each option are shown in Table 10.6.

The first option is $500 million of 20-year straight debt with a coupon of 12%. The second option is for MCI to issue $425 million of equity at a stock price of about $42.50 a share. This represents a discount of about 10% to the stock price of $47 in April 1983. The third option is for MCI to issue $750 million of 20-year convertible debt with a coupon rate of 10% and a conversion price at $55 a share (or roughly a 15% premium to the market) callable after five years.

Drexel, known for its creativity, designed a fourth option for MCI. It was a $1 billion “unit” deal of 20-year debt with a coupon of 9.5% coupled with 18.18 warrants per bond and callable in three years.21 This is called a unit because you purchase two securities at once. (If you recall, MCI’s second equity issue was a unit deal of one share of equity plus warrants to buy equity in the future.) In unit deals, the two securities can be either “attached,” which means they must be traded together, or they can be separable, which means they can be sold as separate securities after being issued. More important, for the potential MCI issue, the bond is “usable,” which in this instance means that the bond can be turned in with the warrants in lieu of cash. If the bond is “used” in this way, its value is equal to $1,000 cash. This type of debt with warrants is sometimes called a synthetic convertible because of how it operates.

Table 10.6 MCI’s Assumed Financing Alternatives in April 1983 (for Fiscal 1984)

Description Amount Raised
(a) 20-year straight debt with a 12% coupon $500 million
(b) Common stock, 1 million shares at $42.50 per share $425 million
(c) 20-year convertible with a 10% coupon convertible at $55 $750 million
(d) A unit offering consisting of a 10-year bond with a coupon of 9.5% and 18.18 warrants per $1,000 bond $1,000 million

This financing instrument is a bit advanced for where we are in this textbook. As a result, we will spend a little time explaining its structure.

The first thing to know is that a warrant is simply an option. The difference between a warrant and most other options traded on an options exchange is that the former is issued by the firm (also normally for a longer period of time), and the latter is written by an options market maker.22 (Options are often called derivatives because their value is “derived” from another asset, in many cases the firm’s stock.)

In the instrument above, the warrant is written to allow the holder to either give the firm a warrant plus $55 in cash for a single share of stock, or give the firm the 18.18 warrants plus the bond and obtain 18.18 shares of stock. Another way of viewing this is that the holder can give the firm $1,000 in cash plus 18.18 warrants and receive 18.18 shares of stock, or the holder can give the firm one bond (with a face value of $1,000) plus 18.18 warrants and receive 18.18 shares of stock. (As should be clear, 18.18 * $55.00 = $1,000.)

This example would be fairly straightforward if the bonds were actually worth $1,000, but in general they are not (they are worth $1,000 if used to convert the warrants as explained in the following paragraph). While the bonds have a face value of $1,000, the coupon on the bond of 9.5% is below the market rate of the 12% for the straight bond in Table 10.6. Thus, as a stand-alone instrument (without the warrants), the bond would trade below $1,000. (If you recall, earlier we mentioned that MCI issued a number of “OID” bonds, i.e., original issue discount bonds with a coupon rate below the market interest rate for bonds of that rating category. As such, these bonds were issued at prices below par.)

Thus, the bonds are worth less than $1,000 if traded alone. However, at the time the warrants are converted, the bonds can be used in lieu of $1,000 cash. Since the bonds can be used in this way, they are termed “usable.” In addition, since the bonds are worth more for this purpose than their stand-alone value, it means most warrant holders will use the bonds instead of cash to convert the warrants into shares. If this happens the bonds will be retired or “extinguished” at the time of the conversion. (If the debt portion of the unit issue are used when the warrants are exercised, then the debt is eliminated and replaced with the new equity.) Thus, this is similar to a convertible bond. At the time of conversion, convertible bonds are also extinguished and converted into equity. For this reason, a unit issue of usable bonds with warrants is called a synthetic convertible.

The discussion above is complex and you may need to reread the previous paragraphs before we go on to ensure you understand.

The decision of when to convert the warrants is similar to the decision of when to convert a convertible bond, which we discussed at the beginning of this chapter. The conversion price for these warrants is $55.00. Now assume MCI’s stock price goes to $70. This does not mean the holder necessarily wants to convert, but it does mean the warrants are worth more. One warrant plus $55 cash will give the holder one share of stock worth $70.

Each unit, consisting of a $1,000 par value bond plus 18.18 warrants, would now be worth $1,272.60 (18.18 * $70). To convert all 18.18 warrants requires either $1,000 cash (18.18 * $55) or the surrender of the bond. Thus, if the warrants are either called or maturing, the holders should convert. And second, as described in the paragraph above, it is in the holders’ financial interest to use the bonds rather than the cash for conversion.23

On an even more advanced note, from a Balance Sheet perspective, it is a little better for a firm to issue debt with warrants than straight debt. The debt with warrants is accounted for as both debt (the bonds) and equity (the warrants) on the Balance Sheet.24 It results in the firm’s having more equity and is thus less likely to violate any debt covenants.

We will now comment on why a firm may want to issue usable debt with warrants rather than either straight or convertible debt. This comment is outside of corporate finance and touches on the investment side of finance. Although not proven, it is sometimes argued, particularly by investment bankers, that firms can issue synthetic convertibles in larger size than either straight debt or convertible debt. This would be true if there were “segmented markets”—that is, if investors do not believe that different types of securities are necessarily substitutes for each other. If that is the case, the debt with warrants can sell in three different market segments: the convertible market (when attached), the straight high-yield (junk) bond market, and the equity/options market (when detached). The rationale is that by selling in three different markets (high-yield bonds, convertible, and equity) the firm can finance a larger amount.

Which one would you choose to do? Straight debt of $500 million at 12%? Equity of $425 million at an issue price of $42.50? Convertibles of $750 million with a coupon of 8% and a conversion price of $55? Or, the unit issue of debt with warrants at $1 billion?

Some may be tempted to simplify this situation by asking: Should the firm choose the option which raises the most cash? The answer is “no.” The firm should choose the option that best fits the firm’s financial policies.

Let’s narrow down our choices a bit with some direct comparisons. From MCI’s point of view, the debt-with-warrants choice dominates the convertibles choice as it has a lower coupon and a higher conversion price. (That is, the interest rate is lower, and it gives away less of the upside stock price.) The debt-with-warrants choice also dominates the straight debt issue choice because it has a much lower coupon and raises more capital. (That is, if the debt with warrants remains debt, MCI would much rather pay 9.5% than 12%.) Thus, when comparing the three debt issues, the debt with warrants is the dominant alternative.

However, before making our decision final, let’s consider the impact of the options on MCI’s capital structure. (We exclude the third option since it is dominated by the fourth.) Table 10.7 compares how each of the remaining three options will impact MCI’s capital structure under two different scenarios. Or as economists state it, two different states of the world. In one state (the first column), MCI does poorly, and the stock price stays constant or falls. In the second state (the third column), MCI does well, and the stock price rises substantially. In the first state, in which MCI’s stock price does not go up, neither the convertibles nor the warrants will convert. In the second state, in which MCI’s stock price rises, both the convertibles and the warrants will convert.

Our remaining three options are sequentially represented in Table 10.7. The base case represents MCI before any new financing. MCI starts with $944 million of debt (of which $400 million is an already issued convertible and the remaining $544 million is straight debt), $500 million of excess cash (which is counted as negative debt), and equity of $766 million.

Without any new financing, MCI’s base case has a 36.7% debt ratio (debt divided by debt plus equity), in state 1 (the first column), compared to 3.6% debt in state 2 (the third column) after the existing $400 million of convertible debt converts. Examining now the financing options:

Option 1—straight debt: MCI issues $500 million of 12%, 20-year straight debt. In the first state (where MCI’s stock price does not rise or possibly falls), the firm now has a capital structure with 55.2% debt. In the second state of the world (where MCI’s stock price rises enough so it can force conversion on the existing convertible), MCI has 31.8% debt. This means if MCI issues straight debt and state 1 of the world ensues, MCI will be a highly leveraged firm that will probably be unable to raise additional debt financing. That is, with a 55.2% debt ratio, it is unlikely that MCI can raise additional debt. In state 2, MCI’s capital structure improves slightly from its current level of 36.7%.

Option 2—equity: MCI issues $425 million in new equity. In state 1, MCI’s debt adjusted for excess cash remains at $444 million, and its equity increases to $1,191 million. With the new equity issue, the debt ratio falls from 36.7% (in the base case before financing) to 27.2%. In state 2, the existing convertible is converted and MCI’s debt ratio falls to 2.7%. Thus, if MCI issues straight equity, its debt ratio remains manageable even in state 1. In either situation, MCI’s debt ratio is low enough that future debt financing is possible in the near term. (Again, for ease of exposition, we excluded the third option since it is dominated by the fourth.)

Option 4—unit deal debt with warrants: MCI issues an additional $1 billion in debt and warrants, assuming the debt is valued at $750 million and the warrants are valued at $250 million. In this case, MCI’s debt adjusted for excess cash increases to $1,194 million, and the equity increases to $1,116 million. In state 1, MCI’s debt ratio increases to 51.7%, while in state 2, it falls to 1.9%. This looks similar to Option 1, debt financing, in state 1 (without conversion) and similar to option 2, equity financing, in state 2 (with conversion).

Let’s summarize: As seen in Table 10.7, if MCI’s stock price does not rise (state 1), then the debt ratio fluctuates from 36.7% in the base case to 55.2% with a $500 million straight debt issue, to 27.2% with an equity issue and 51.7% with a $1 billion debt-and-warrants issue.

Table 10.7 MCI’s Capital Structure under Alternative Financing Choices

Base Case: No New Debt or Equity Issued MCI Does Poorly Possible Conversion MCI Does Well
March 1983 ($000s)
Existing convertible debt 400 –400 0
Straight debt 544 544
Excess cash (500) (500)
Total debt adjusted for excess cash 444 –400 44
Equity 766 +400 1,166
Total debt + equity 1,210 1,210
Debt ratio 36.7% 3.6%
Option 1: MCI issues $500 million straight debt
March 1983 ($000s)
Existing convertible debt 400 –400 0
Straight debt (+500) 1,044 1,044
Excess cash (500) (500)
Total debt adjusted for excess cash 944 –400 544
Equity 766 +400 1,166
Total debt + equity 1,710 1,710
Debt ratio 55.2% 31.8%
Option 2: MCI issues $425 million of new equity
March 1983 ($000s)
Existing convertible debt 400 –400 0
Straight debt 544 544
Excess cash (500) (500)
Total debt adjusted for excess cash 444 –400 44
Equity (+425) 1,191 +400 1,591
Total debt + equity 1,635 1,635
Debt ratio 27.2% 2.7%
Option 4: MCI issues $1 billion unit deal*
March 1983 ($000s)
Existing convertible debt (+750) 1,150 –1,150 0
Straight debt 544 544
Excess cash (500) (500)
Total debt adjusted for excess cash 1,194 –1,150 44
Equity (+250) 1,116 +1,150 2,266
Total debt + equity 2,310 2,310
Debt ratio 51.7% 1.9%

*Remember, a unit deal is a bond with warrants.

In state 2, MCI’s stock price increases, and everything converts (the existing convertible debt becomes equity in all of the cases, and in Option 4 the new debt also converts to equity). In this situation, MCI’s debt ratio fluctuates from 3.6% in the base case to 31.8% with the straight debt issue, 2.7% with the equity issue, or 1.9% with the debt-and-warrant issue.

As discussed earlier in the chapter, a convertible is essentially a bond with an embedded call option. As such, the option is not separable from the bond. The MCI debt with warrants being discussed here allows the firm to essentially issue the debt and options as separate issues. By making the debt usable (the debt can be used instead of cash) in exercising the warrant, MCI is forcing the debt issue to act like a convertible when the warrant is called. If the debt was not usable, MCI would basically be issuing $750 million in debt and $250 million in equity, and the debt would remain after the warrant was called. It is the usability that makes it a synthetic convertible. If it walks like a duck and quacks like a duck, then for our purposes when the day is over it is a duck (i.e., a convertible).

 

Summary Comparison of Debt Ratios Without Conversion If Converted
March 1983 ($000s)
Base Case: No new debt or equity issued 36.7% 3.6%
Option 1: MCI issues $500 million straight debt 55.2% 31.8%
Option 2: MCI issues $425 million of new equity 27.2% 2.7%
Option 4: MCI issues $1 billion unit deal 51.7% 1.9%

MCI’s Financing Choice

Let’s return to the question: What should MCI issue? As we saw, among MCI’s choices, straight debt is dominated by debt with warrants. Even if the bond-with-warrants issue does not convert, it allows MCI to issue a larger amount at a lower interest rate. Convertible debt is also dominated by usable debt with the warrants: MCI can issue a larger amount with better terms than those of convertible debt.

What about choosing to do both options 1 and 2, that is issue both debt and equity? The unit issue of debt with warrants is slightly superior to the combined debt and equity issues. Why? In state 1 the two options have roughly the same amount of debt and roughly the same amount of financing raised. The debt with warrants has a much lower interest rate on the debt but it has twice as much debt, so the net effect is that there is a higher total interest charge on the debt with warrants. However, in state 2, the unit deal of debt with warrant financing is clearly superior once the debt is converted.

This means the real choice for MCI is between issuing straight equity, or usable debt with warrants. So now we clearly come to the part of corporate finance where there is no precise, correct answer. Should MCI issue equity or the debt with warrants?

If MCI issues equity, the firm has $425 million of funding, and it has the lowest debt ratio in state 1. If MCI issues debt with warrants, it is riskier, but the firm will have $1 billion of funding regardless and the lowest debt ratio in state 2. It is probably worth noting here that if MCI did not take risks, the firm would never exist. This was, after all, a start-up company that went after AT&T, one of the world’s largest monopolies.

What did MCI do? Note, your authors would probably not be discussing a usable debt-with-warrants issue if one did not actually exist. MCI issued the debt with warrants in July 1983.25 What happened next? Profits were not as high as forecast in our pro formas. AT&T cut rates once it was allowed to do so, and the Baby Bells were allowed by the FCC to increase the interconnect charges. As a result, MCI also had to cut rates while its costs increased, both of which lowered the firm’s margins. MCI’s revenues went from $1 billion to $4 billion over the next five years. However, MCI’s net income went from $171 million to $88 million over the same five years.

MCI Postscript

MCI’s stock price peaked at $47 in July 1983, and, for most of the projected period discussed in this chapter, from 1983 to 1988, the stock price fluctuated around $10 a share. As a consequence, all of the convertible debt (which was convertible at $53 per share) remained on the Balance Sheet, as did the warrants. (That is, none of it converted.) MCI’s debt ratios rose from 55.2% (not adjusted for excess cash) in 1983 to 68% at the end of 1987. What happened next? MCI not only suffered in the short term, but to avoid cutting capital expenditures too much, the firm had to cut back on its marketing costs.

Recall that MCI was competing in “elections” for long-distance-carrier market share during this time, which meant marketing expenditures were essential. These elections had been ordered by the courts and would occur only once. If MCI did not win these elections, when would the next opportunity be? Never. After the elections, MCI would have to gain new customers one by one. When we examined Massey Ferguson we talked about its losing markets permanently to Korean and Japanese firms. With MCI, any customers lost in the election were losses in market share for a long time period, if not forever.

So what did MCI do? The firm began to “shop” itself (i.e., it started looking for a merger partner to acquire the firm). The problem was that no one wanted to buy MCI. Eventually IBM bought 18% of MCI’s equity. However, IBM did not pay cash using its telecommunication operations (which had not been successful) as payment instead.

Now suppose MCI had issued equity and the world changed as it did. What could MCI have done then? Perhaps issue more equity, maybe issue more debt. MCI’s debt ratios would definitely have been lower. Would this have been enough to avoid cutting marketing expenses? Perhaps, but not with certainty.

In addition, McGowan, who was CEO of MCI and ran it throughout this period, had a heart attack and a subsequent heart transplant in 1991. Interestingly, MCI did not announce his heart attack or transplant until two weeks after the fact. The SEC investigated and ruled that even though McGowan was the CEO of the firm, his absence and medical condition due to a heart transplant was not material information that investors needed to know.26

McGowan gave up his position as CEO after his heart transplant and died in June 1992 at the age of 64. At the time of his death, MCI had annual sales of $10.5 billion, net earnings of $609 million, and 31,000 employees. The company had also accomplished its goal of providing nationwide phone service. In 1993, British Telecom paid $4.3 billion for a 20% stake in MCI.

A last aside: On September 14, 1998, MCI merged with WorldCom in a $40 billion deal. From 1998 to 2000, the firm was called MCI WorldCom. From 2000 to 2003, the MCI name was dropped, and the firm became WorldCom. WorldCom filed for bankruptcy on July 21, 2002 (the largest bankruptcy filing in the United States at the time) after having overstated total assets by an estimated $11 billion (the largest fraud in the United States up until that time).27 In 2003, the firm changed its name back to MCI (as noted in Chapter 5, firms in bankruptcy tend to change their names). The firm was purchased by Verizon Communications in January 2006 and is now part of Verizon’s operations.

Summary

It is important to remember that MCI was the smallest firm in its industry. It was also the riskiest firm in its industry. In addition, this was a period of tremendous business risk due to deregulation and the “phone elections.” Given this combination, a firm does not necessarily want to have the highest debt ratio in the industry. Now if stock prices had gone up, the firm would have been fine. Unfortunately, they did not go up, and MCI ended up looking a bit like Massey, with AT&T playing the role of John Deere. In addition, MCI was a lot smaller in relationship to AT&T than Massey was to Deere.

Let us summarize:

  1. Financial policies should support a firm’s investment strategy.
  2. Financial policies not only concern a firm’s debt/equity ratio, they also concern the firm’s choice of debt (long versus short, fixed versus floating, etc.), the type of equity (i.e., preferred, convertibles, etc.), the dividend policy, and more.
  3. Financial policies must be consistent with each other. Remember the overview of the corporate finance diagram, which we have discussed twice. It starts with a firm’s product market strategy and financial strategy. The financial policies in the chart (under financial strategy in Chapter 1) must be consistent with each other. This is another way of saying these policies are not separate. For example, a firm does not just randomly set a dividend policy. The amount a firm pays in dividends is integrated into the amount the firm will need to raise in external financing, which is then integrated into the firm’s capital structure.
  4. Financial policies convey information. Because of asymmetric information, investors interpret financial policy decisions as signals.
  5. Asymmetric information and signaling create a reluctance by firms to cut dividends and a reluctance to issue equity. This creates a pecking order that makes sustainable growth and internally created funds preferable to outside financing.
  6. There are a number of hybrid instruments that are designed to mitigate this signaling effect (e.g., like convertibles, PERCS).28 How a firm obtains its financing matters.
  7. A firm must not only decide what its static financial policies are, it must also worry about the dynamic of how the firm obtains them. The dynamics of overshooting or undershooting a static policy must be understood. In addition, a firm’s financial policies must change with changes in its product market strategies (as we saw in Chapter 7 with the Marriott).

Remember: All firms need to set policies, these policies have to be consistent, and policies convey information.

A Review of What We Have Covered So Far

Let us now do an even larger review of this section. We began this section with Massey and showed that financing matters. We examined the “old” Marriott and its policies. Then we saw Marriott change its product market policy from owning and operating hotels (with a large capital base and need for funds) to only operating hotels (with a much lower capital base and need for funds). We then discussed how this change in product market strategy created a need to change the financial policies for the “new” Marriott. In Chapter 9, we analyzed the old AT&T with its financial needs and policies. When AT&T changed, due to deregulation and divestiture, we analyzed the new AT&T and derived its new policies. Finally, we looked at the old MCI—which had no policies. When MCI’s competitive environment changed, we asked: What should its new policies be? Thus, we have done the link between product market policies and financial policies six times. Three times with the “old” firms and three times with the “new” firms after there were changes in product markets.

Coming Attractions

The next chapter explores another financial policy, what dividend level to pay. We will use Apple Inc.’s decision to begin paying a dividend to illustrate dividend policy.

Appendix 10A: Development of MCI’s Pro Formas 1984–1988

MCI’s pro formas, Tables 10A.1, 10A.2, and 10A.3 (as all pro formas), can be generated many different ways. In the real world, numerous sensitivity analyses would be done, including Monte Carlo simulations. However, as this is not part of our lesson for this chapter, and for simplicity, your authors have generated a set of pro formas using the following assumptions. (We are assuming that a reader who has been with us since the beginning of the book will understand how pro formas are generated and will be able to change the assumptions and generate his own pro formas.) In what follows, we list the line items in the pro formas one by one and briefly state our assumptions.

Table 10A.1 MCI Pro Forma Income Statement 1984–1988: Expected Case

($000’s) 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988
Sales 1,738,662 2,625,379 3,675,531 4,778,190 5,686,046
Interconnect, install, and operations 695,465 1,050,152 1,470,212 1,911,276 2,274,419
Marketing, general, and administrative 521,599 787,613 1,102,660 1,433,458 1,705,814
Depreciation 174,874 272,753 384,618 459,441 480,566
 Total 1,391,938 2,110,518 2,957,490 3,804,175 4,460,799
Income from operations 346,724 514,861 718,041 974,016 1,225,247
Interest expense 132,150 161,374 284,382 402,967 402,459
Profit before tax 214,574 353,487 433,659 571,048 822,788
Income tax 75,101 123,720 151,781 199,867 287,976
Net profit 139,473 229,767 281,878 371,182 534,812
Times interest (EBIT/I) 2.62 3.19 2.52 2.42 3.04
Sales Growth 62.0% 51.0% 40.0% 30.0% 19.0%

Table 10A.2 MCI Pro Forma Balance Sheet 1984–1988: Expected Case

($000’s) 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988
Cash 86,933 131,269 183,777 238,910 284,302
Accounts receivable 208,639 315,045 441,064 573,382 682,326
Other current assets 9,566 9,566 9,566 9,566 9,566
Current assets 305,138 455,880 634,406 821,858 976,194
PP&E net 2,173,327 3,281,724 4,410,637 4,778,190 4,833,139
Other assets 33,137 33,137 33,137 33,137 33,137
Total assets 2,511,602 3,770,741 5,078,180 5,633,185 5,842,470
Long-term debt—current 48,038 48,038 48,038 48,038 48,038
Accounts payable 295,572 446,314 624,840 812,292 966,628
Advances and other 70,728 70,728 70,728 70,728 70,728
Current liabilities 414,338 565,080 743,606 931,058 1,085,394
Long-term debt 1,104,634 1,983,264 2,830,299 2,826,671 2,346,807
Other 87,525 87,525 87,525 87,525 87,525
Total liabilities 1,606,497 2,635,869 3,661,431 3,845,254 3,519,726
Contributed capital 588,948 588,948 588,948 588,948 588,948
Retained earnings (deficit) 316,157 545,924 827,802 1,198,983 1,733,796
Total shareholders’ equity 905,105 1,134,872 1,416,750 1,787,931 2,322,744
Total liabilities and equity 2,511,602 3,770,741 5,078,180 5,633,185 5,842,470
Debt ratio (D/(D + E)) 56.0% 64.2% 67.0% 61.7% 50.8%

Table 10A.3 MCI’s Pro Forma Cash Flows 1984–1988: Expected Case (also Table 10.5)

($000’s) 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988
Net income 139,473 229,767 281,878 371,182 534,812
Depreciation 174,875 272,753 384,618 459,441 480,567
Change in working capital
Cash from operations 314,348 502,520 666,496 830,623 1,015,379
Capital expenditures 1,024,036 1,381,150 1,513,531 826,994 535,516
Preferred stock dividends
Funds required 1,024,036 1,381,150 1,513,531 826,994 535,516
Net financing required 709,688 878,630 847,035 (3,629) (479,863)

Sales: As noted in the text, your authors assume MCI’s sales will both grow as the market for long-distance telecommunication grows and as MCI increases its market share (we also assume the growth in MCI’s market share slows over time). The pro forma assumes the overall market grows at 8% for the entire period and that MCI increases its share by 50% the first year, then 40%, 30%, 20%, and 10% by 1988. This produces a net increase in sales of 62%, 51%, 40%, 30%, and 19% for the years 1984–1988, respectively.

Interconnect, installation, and operations costs: Set at 40% of sales throughout the forecast period, as that was the average over the 1978–1983 period.

Marketing, general, and administration expenses: Set at 30% of sales, which is higher than the 20% average over the 1978–1983 period. We assume this increase will happen because MCI will likely have to increase its advertising and marketing effort and expenses in order to capture market share.

Depreciation: The average PP&E (the average of the opening and closing amounts) is reduced evenly over 10 years (i.e., using straight-line depreciation).

Interest expense: Calculated as the opening amount of total debt (short-term debt plus long-term debt) times 14% (which is about 3% above the U.S. 10-year rate at the time).

Income tax: Set at 35% of profit before tax.

Cash: Set at 5% of sales (the median value from 1978–1983).29

Accounts receivable: Set at 12% of sales (the average value from 1978–1983).

Other assets: Both current and long-term other assets are, for simplicity, assumed to remain constant over this time period.

PP&E: This is set at 125% of sales in 1984 and 1985, 120% of sales in 1986, 100% of sales in 1987, and 85% of sales in 1988 (this gets us almost no change in 1988). This is done because, as noted in the text, the firm’s investments in its network (CAPEX) should fall over time, causing the PP&E/sales ratio to increase.

Current portion of long-term debt: This is assumed to remain constant over time.

Accounts payable: Set at 17% of sales (the average value from 1978–1983).

Advances and other liabilities: Assumed constant over this time period.

Long-term debt: This is the plug or balancing figure.

Other assets: This is assumed to remain constant over this time period.

Contributed capital: Assumed to remain constant over this time period.

Retained earnings: Assumed to increase with net income (MCI is assumed to not pay any dividends).

Notes

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset