Chapter 26
Compensating Public Sector Employees

Jared J. Llorens

Developing effective compensation systems for public sector employees remains a core challenge for human resource management professionals, public managers, and elected representatives at all levels of government, both nationally and internationally. This challenge is often made more complex due to the breadth and scope of public sector employment, as well as the rapidly evolving needs and expectations of employees and the public at large. Public sector compensation practices have historically developed alongside traditional civil service systems and in response to longstanding patronage abuses. They have placed a priority on such tenets as internal wage equity, centralized and standardized pay administration, modest pay rates, strong nonwage benefit packages, and relative job security. While these traditional systems have been viewed as quite effective in limiting the harmful effects of favoritism and discrimination, their adherence to the tenets mentioned above has also made them a constant target of reform efforts, and in many respects, the push and pull of these efforts continue to dominate contemporary debates surrounding appropriate systems for compensating public employees.

This chapter first discusses the broader environmental context that public compensation systems operate within and how this contrasts with their private sector counterparts. Next, it takes a detailed look at efforts to transform public compensation systems, focusing specifically on the topics of performance-based pay, public and private pay comparability, and fiscally driven retirement benefits reform. Finally, the chapter discusses contemporary challenges facing compensation systems and concludes with practical advice for public managers and policymakers seeking to address these evolving challenges.

The Unique Context of Public Sector Compensation

In addressing what defines and characterizes effective compensation practice, it is helpful to first discuss the unique environmental context of public compensation systems and how this context has shaped many of the debates over what constitutes fair and equitable compensation for public sector employment. In a broad sense, wage and nonwage benefits are the core components of employee compensation in both the public and private sectors. Together, these two components represent the essential elements of any total compensation package, and for most employers, the overriding goal is to provide a package or mix of wage and nonwage benefits sufficient to meet existing and future human capital needs. Though this goal may be common to all sectors of employment, major differences exist in the extent to which public and private employers are able to tailor their compensation practices to their individual workforce needs.

In contrast to their public sector counterparts, private sector employers typically enjoy near absolute freedom in adapting their compensation systems to their unique human capital needs. Beyond adherence to federal, state, and local labor laws (e.g., minimum wage rate and antidiscrimination statutes), there are relatively few limits to what private employers may provide to their employees. For instance, a great deal of attention has been paid to executive compensation in recent years in light of the economic downturn resulting from the collapse of the US housing market. Chief executive officers (CEOs) of major national and international corporations typically enjoy base salaries in the millions of dollars, stock options in the case of publicly traded companies, and employment perks such as personal drivers. Consider the wage-based compensation of Michael Duke, former CEO of Walmart. In 2013, he earned approximately $5.6 million in base salary; his total salary, including stock options, was approximately $20.6 million (Reuters, 2014). Although many members of the public might find such compensation packages to be excessive or unnecessary, their use is perfectly acceptable given the nature of private sector employment. The compensation package was developed and approved by corporate board members and, ultimately, the shareholders of Walmart.

Public sector compensation systems function in a substantially different environmental context. Overall, public employee compensation is statutorily grounded and tied directly to the discretion of elected representatives, tax revenue streams, and public perceptions of compensation fairness and equity. As a result of these differences, public compensation systems have historically developed under a unique set of practical constraints. First, the statutory basis of public employee compensation has resulted in systems that have been characterized as slow to adapt to shifting labor markets and are typically centralized, standardized, and rule bound (Kettl, Ingraham, Sanders, & Horner, 1996; Llorens & Battaglio, 2010). At most levels of government, compensation systems are built on mandated processes of job analysis and classification where jobs are rated and ranked according to such factors as their complexity, educational requirements, and level of responsibility. Once classified, jobs are then assigned wage rates on the basis of their ranking, thus ensuring internal wage equity across occupations within an organization and constraining the ability of managers to, appropriately, or inappropriately, influence wage rates on the basis of performance or nonperformance related factors.

Second, the role of elected representatives in setting overall wage rates, adjusting wage rates according to changing labor market conditions, and deciding on nonwage benefit levels has also constrained the ability of public managers to tailor compensation practices to their unique human capital needs. While private organizations are accountable only to their owners or shareholders in determining appropriate wage and benefit levels, elected leaders are accountable to their constituents and prevailing public views of appropriate compensation for public employees. In practice, this has resulted in a general reluctance by elected leaders to set public sector wage rates at or above comparable private sector rates due to their immediacy and public visibility. However, this reluctance has resulted in a greater willingness by elected leaders to provide more generous, long-term, nonwage benefits in the form of employee pensions (Pew Center on the States, 2010).

Third, the near total reliance on tax revenues to fund public employee compensation has placed distinct limits on the manner in which public employees are compensated. While private employers may seek to provide wages and nonwage benefits at levels commensurate with their operating profits, public managers are limited by both the extent of tax revenues received by a particular governmental entity and the discretion of elected leaders in allocating tax revenues to employee compensation. In practice, this has often resulted in a general inability of public managers to provide significant performance rewards, common in many private sector labor markets, or to advocate for overall wage increases that would require the generation of new tax revenues. Furthermore, this reliance on tax revenues has also resulted in calls for compensation reform due to the increasing costs of public employee retirement benefits and a broader unwillingness to increase tax rates to maintain existing benefits.

The Case of the US Federal Government

The US federal government's General Schedule (GS) compensation system stands out as a concrete example of how traditional civil service compensation systems are influenced by their statutory and political environment. Most rank-and-file federal employees work within the GS system where their occupations are classified and compensated according to guidelines established in such statutes as Title V of the US Code and the Federal Employees' Pay Comparability Act of 1990 (FEPCA). Occupations are assigned a grade level on a scale of 1 to 15, with 15 representing the highest occupational grade. Using national salary data provided by the US Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS), each grade level is assigned an entry-level wage rate, which can vary by geographic location, and each grade is further broken down into ten hierarchical steps that traditionally have been used to reward seniority. In terms of establishing and maintaining wage competitiveness, the US president is responsible for recommending annual pay adjustments to the US Congress, and although the FEPCA calls for federal wage rates to fall within 5 percent of comparable private sector wages, no president since its passage has recommended increasing wage rates to levels sufficient to meet this standard. BLS estimates that federal wages are approximately 14 to 15 percent below comparable private sector wages, but despite evidence that the wage gap is driven by below-market wage rates for higher-graded employees, current policy holds that annual wage adjustments be made uniformly across all fifteen grade levels (Condrey, Facer, & Llorens, 2013).

To illustrate how the GS system performs in practice, consider the case of a recent MPA graduate hired as a management analyst within the Department of the Interior in Washington, DC. Formally classified to the GS-0343 occupational series, the new analyst would be eligible for appointment to grade level 9 due to her educational attainment. If this were her first position within the federal government, she would also be appointed at step 1, the first step within the grade. She would receive a salary of exactly $52,146 per year, the same as any other applicant hired at the same grade level (US Office of Personnel Management, 2014). However, if the newly hired management analyst were to be offered a competing position with a management consulting firm at an annual salary of $60,000, there would be no standard means for her hiring manager to increase her starting salary due to guidelines set forth in GS pay administration policies. In the same vein, if the new management analyst turned out to be an extremely high-performing employee, there would be no standard means for her manager to raise her salary to reward her outstanding performance without promoting her to an occupation graded at a higher level. Finally, if the results of salary surveys indicated that occupations at grade level 9 were systematically underpaid compared to their private sector counterparts, there would be no means for increasing the overall pay of the grade level without also increasing the pay of all grade levels, whether or not they were found to be overpaid or underpaid.

Despite public sector compensation systems' general prioritization of internal wage equity and their enhanced capacity to limit favoritism, discrimination, and patronage abuses, the consequences of their unique environmental context have resulted in three major areas of concern for policymakers, public managers, and public administration scholars: performance-based compensation, pay comparability, and postemployment benefits.

Performance-Based Compensation

Inherent limitations in the ability of traditional compensation systems to recognize outstanding employee performance have resulted in two major performance-based reform initiatives: merit pay, also referred to as pay for performance, and pay banding, also referred to as broadbanding. Of the two reforms, merit pay is perhaps the more commonly proposed and has received the most scholarly attention. The basic intent of merit pay plans is to develop pay practices that link wage rate levels or salary increases to employee performance measurement outcomes. The underlying premise is that by this linking, organizations can more effectively encourage individual performance and increase the overall level of organizational performance. Merit pay reform efforts have their roots in the US Civil Service Reform Act of 1978, which implemented merit pay reforms for senior federal employees. As a component of broader new public management reform initiatives, merit pay reforms were later adopted at the state and local government levels in the United States and internationally in such countries as Australia, Canada, and the Netherlands (Ingraham, 1993; Kellough & Lu, 1993; Cardona, 2007).

Despite their continued and widespread adoption, scholarship on the impact of merit pay reforms has consistently shown that in most circumstances, merit pay compensation practices do not achieve their goal of increasing employee or organizational performance (Cardona, 2007; Perry, Engbers, & Jun, 2009; Bowman, 2010).

As part of a jointly sponsored research effort by the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development and the European Union (EU), Cardona (2007) found no empirical support for merit pay reforms having a positive impact on performance or motivation for managerial and nonmanagerial employees. Instead, he points out that prior reviews of merit pay implementation in EU member countries identified a number of shortcomings, including the inability to adequately measure employee performance for many occupations, “costly and time-consuming” processes, and an inability to effectively address underperformance (p. 3). Cardona posits that it may be more beneficial to maintain traditional compensation systems with strong ties to pay grades since they provide a “greater deal of predictability for employees and reduce the likelihood of arbitrariness in determining individual salaries” (p. 6).

In analyzing over fifty-seven studies of merit pay, Perry et al. (2009) find that “performance-related pay in the public sector consistently fails to deliver on its promise” of such benefits as increased individual and organizational performance (p. 43):

  • Merit pay plans have typically fallen short in changing employee perceptions of the relationship between their compensation and performance.
  • Merit pay plans are commonly affected by organizational factors such as the quality or effectiveness of an employee performance appraisal system and the levels of financial incentives tied to employee performance appraisals.
  • Merit pay plans are likely to experience greater odds of success for positions “in which job responsibilities are fairly concrete and measurable” (p. 44).
  • Differences in institutional frameworks between the public and private sectors, such as the transparency inherent in public sector compensation systems, may play a greater role in limiting the successful implementation of merit pay plans.
  • Theoretical frameworks more closely aligned with public employment (e.g., public service motivation) may be better resources for seeking to improve public employee performance.

Echoing many of Perry et al.'s (2009) observation, Bowman (2010) highlights an often cited report by the US Merit Systems Protection Board (2006) asserting that the successful implementation of merit pay plans requires public organizations to possess the following characteristics: “a culture that supports pay for performance; effective and fair supervisors; a rigorous performance evaluation system; adequate funding; a system of checks and balances to ensure fairness; appropriate training for supervisors and employees; and an ongoing system evaluation” (p. xii). However, even if these requirements are met within an organization, Bowman aptly points out that the implementation of such pay plans may result in unintended consequences such as a focus on short-term outcomes or reduced performance as a result of limited expectations.

Pay banding has often been proposed by compensation reformers for its ability to provide greater managerial flexibility in setting employee wage rates. Under these plans, traditional, fixed-rate pay grades are consolidated into a smaller number of pay bands with corresponding maximum and minimum pay ranges. Managers are then granted the discretion to set the pay rate for an individual employee anywhere within the occupation's corresponding pay band. For example, if a particular occupation is placed within a pay band with a minimum annual salary of $50,000 and a maximum salary of $80,000, a manager hiring a new employee within this band would be able to set the pay rate anywhere within that range.

While pay-banding has not experienced the same level of attention as merit pay in the broader literature, its related reform initiatives have experienced a similar record of success as a result of many of the same challenges that merit pay plans face. For example, Whalen and Guy (2008) provide a comprehensive overview of pay-banding adoption across US state government and an in-depth study of implementation challenges in three states. They report adoption by only twelve states, with limited adoption by an additional four states. The states that considered pay-banding reform but chose not to move forward with implementation communicated their skepticism of the potential benefits of pay-banding reforms over traditional compensation systems. In addition, the states selected for a more detailed analysis indicated significant problems with the implementation of their reforms. Two of the primary reasons for implementation failure were insufficient funding for potential salaries within pay bands and a lack of formal discretion delegated to managers to set individual pay rates.

Comparative Compensation

Related to the challenge of using existing public compensation systems to reward high-performing employees, there has been a renewed discussion on the competitiveness of public sector wages, especially given scholarship evaluating the impact of pay on key human capital metrics. One of the primary goals of broader compensation strategies is to ensure that organizations possess the necessary human capital to fulfill their missions. Conventional wisdom has held that organizations unable to meet this goal will likely experience the harmful effects of decreased employee satisfaction and increased employee turnover or turnover intent.

Overall, there have been mixed findings concerning the relationship between compensation and turnover, one of the most common measures associated with effective human capital management. For example, research has commonly found pay to be a predictor of job satisfaction (Ellickson & Logsdon, 2001), and prior research has found evidence of an indirect relationship between job satisfaction and turnover intent (Moynihan & Pandey, 2008). Research has also found support for the indirect impact of pay satisfaction on turnover intent (Bertelli, 2007), even when controlling for organizational satisfaction (Lee & Whitford, 2008). Turnover intent, however, is not operationally equivalent to actual employee turnover. While research has found support for the indirect impact of pay levels on voluntary turnover rates (Selden & Moynihan, 2000), more recent research did not find a significant relationship between relative pay rates (public and private pay gaps) on voluntary turnover (Llorens & Stazyk, 2011). This somewhat contradictory finding is most likely explained by the role that defined-benefit compensation programs have played in retaining public sector employees. Since two of the core characteristics of defined-benefit pay plans are their nonportability and link between years of service and final benefit levels, it is not uncommon for public employees to remain with their employer despite dissatisfaction with their overall pay levels.

Although absolute pay comparability between the public and private sectors (external equity) has not traditionally been one of the goals of public sector compensation systems, given perceived public sector employment benefits like job security and the opportunity to serve the public interest, there has been a growing debate on the extent to which public sector pay is comparable to private sector pay. Much of this research has been driven by two sometimes competing perspectives. From the perspective of many public sector employers, there has been a growing acceptance that for many occupations, public sector wages are simply too low to compete for high-quality job candidates, especially in the science and technology fields (US Bureau of Labor Statistics, 2009). This drive to remain competitive in the broader labor market has been the catalyst for such pay reforms as FEPCA, which instituted differential federal pay rates by geographic location (locality pay) and set a goal of federal pay rates falling within 5 percent of comparable private sector pay rates. Overall, FEPCA has been quite successful in increasing federal pay rates in high-cost geographic regions such as northern California and the upper East Coast. However, the movement toward full pay comparability has not been as successful.

In contrast to the prevailing view of many public employers on the competitiveness of their wages, there is a competing perspective, held by many nongovernmental organizations and independent researchers, that public sector employees are in some circumstances overpaid when compared to their private sector counterparts. Miller (1996) notes that the basis for competing perspectives on the state of public sector pay lies in the fact that from a methodological standpoint, one can come to drastically different conclusions on pay comparability depending on how comparisons are made and the underlying data used to estimate wage differences. For example, if average wages are compared between the public sector and private sector, results can often be contradictory. Individual-level data provided by US Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS, 2011) suggest that US public sector workers are overpaid compared to their private sector counterparts. However, using data from an international survey of public and private sector employees, Taylor and Taylor (2011) find that US public sector employees are underpaid compared to the private sector counterparts, while public sector employees in countries such as Canada, Spain, and Japan are considerably overpaid. Both of these results, however, mask the occupational differences in employment sectors, such that the average wage for private sector employment is driven down by low-wage, service sector occupations that generally have no equivalent in the public sector.

To address this shortcoming, researchers have commonly used one of two additional means of comparing public and private pay: occupational and individual comparisons. Given its annual mandate for providing comparisons of federal and private sector to the president, BLS routinely surveys the salaries of private sector occupations that are comparable to those in the federal service. Results using this occupation-based approach have consistently found that federal salaries for lower-graded occupations fall above comparable market rates, while salaries for high-graded occupations fall below comparable market rates (Condrey et al., 2013). These results at the federal level have also been replicated for the public sector as a whole, with prior research pointing out that on average, lower-skilled occupations in the public sector tend to experience higher relative wage rates, while higher-skilled occupations tend to experience lower relative wage rates (Donahue, 2008).

A second method of estimating wage comparability, primarily used in the labor economics literature, compares the wages of individual workers in the public and private sectors while controlling for common human capital characteristics such as age, education, and experience (the human capital approach). Results derived from this approach vary considerably, with evidence of both public sector wage premiums and penalties, dependent on such factors as level of government, geographic location, union strength, ethnicity, and gender (Center for State and Local Government Excellence, 2011). For instance, research using this methodological approach has found evidence that women and minorities in the public sector often enjoy higher wages than their private sector counterparts, arguably due in part to the wage discrimination protections inherent in traditional civil service classification and compensation systems (Llorens, Wenger, & Kellough, 2008).

Retirement Benefits

Along with the difficulty in making broad assessments concerning the overall competitiveness of public sector wage rates, the Great Recession prompted a renewed focus on nonwage compensation in the public sector, particularly postemployment retirement benefits.

Public employers face considerably different decision processes when seeking to develop an appropriate mix of wage and nonwage benefits. In practice, the public and political nature of the wage- and benefit-setting process has resulted in government wage rates that have historically been perceived as falling below comparable market rates for many occupations in the public sector. Underlying this perceived norm of modest or below-market wage rates is the common opinion that public sector employment possesses a number of unique benefits not found in private sector employment. First and foremost, public sector employment has been considered much more stable than private sector employment since public agencies are rarely eliminated and government entities can always raise additional revenue through tax increases to fund operations. Public employment has also been viewed as a form of public service by both employees and the general public. As a result of these factors, highly competitive pay rates have not been viewed as critical to staffing and maintaining a high-quality workforce.

While job security and the opportunity for public service have been viewed as significant benefits to public sector employment, generous retirement benefits have also been used as a means of increasing the attractiveness or competitiveness of public sector compensation packages in both the United States and internationally (Pew Center on the States, 2010; Ponds, Severinson, & Yermo, 2011). Retirement benefits are typically distinguished between more traditional defined-benefit plans (pensions) and more recently adopted defined-contribution plans (401k-style plans). Defined-benefit plans, once the norm for large public and private employers, promise a lifetime benefit to retired employees and commonly require employees to contribute a percentage of their annual wages into an employer-managed fund during their active employment. Contribution rates during employed years can vary at the discretion of the employer, along with aspects such as vesting requirements and final benefit levels. The defining characteristics of these plans are their nonportability and promise of lifetime benefits to retirees regardless of the performance of invested pension contributions made by employees and employers.

Newer defined-contribution plans differ substantially from their older defined-benefit counterparts. Originally developed as supplemental retirement options, these plans provide employees with the option of contributing a percentage of their wages to an employee-managed retirement fund with both employee contributions and employer matching contributions. Employees are typically granted the discretion of determining what percentage of their wages will be placed into the fund, and employers have the discretion of matching employee contributions at a rate they feel appropriate. Unlike defined-benefit plans, employees, not employers, are responsible for managing the investment of their retirement account according to their individual risk tolerance. Most important, on retirement, employees receive the invested balance of their retirement fund that can be converted into an annuity or taken as a lump-sum payment. The balance of a retirement account represents all that employees will have during their retirement years, which can potentially be exhausted if an employee has not saved enough during employment, has experienced significant investment losses, or has a longer-than-anticipated life expectancy. Employers, however, view these plans as a more favorable benefit option since they cut long-term retiree obligations. Over the past thirty years, most private sector employers have abandoned their traditional pension plans in favor of defined-contribution plans (Jaffe, 2004). Recent estimates published by BLS (2014) show that only 19 percent of private sector employees in the United States have access to defined-benefit retirement plans, while over 59 percent have access to defined-contribution plans.

Unlike their private sector counterparts, public employers have, by and large, maintained their defined-benefit plans, and for many in the public sector, they are viewed as more beneficial due to their traditionally low risk and guarantee of lifetime benefits regardless of market performance. The BLS (2014) estimates that approximately 83 percent of state and local government employees still have access to defined-benefit retirement plans, while only 32 percent have access to defined-contribution plans. Prior research has also pointed out that since the characteristics of defined-benefit plans have not received the same level of public scrutiny as wage rate levels, many public employers have historically opted for increasing the generosity of pension benefits in lieu of increased wage rates (Pew Center on the States, 2010). While increases in public pension benefits did not receive a great deal of attention during the economic boom years of the 1990s and early 2000s, there have been increasing alarms concerning the unsustainability of such plans in light of widespread losses in government pension funds since 2007.

While private-defined benefit plans in the United States are insured by the Pension Benefit Guarantee Corporation in case private employers go out of business, public plans receive no such insurance. As a result, public employers are responsible for covering retirement obligations regardless of the performance of their pension investments. The Pew Charitable Trust has been one of the leading voices calling attention to this issue in recent years. In 2010, it estimated that state and local government pension funds were underfunded by approximately $757 billion, and without significant reforms, many states and localities would be forced to cut vital services in order to meet their obligations to retirees. At the state level, Illinois stands out for its low level of pension funding and impending cutbacks due to rising pension costs. As a result of such factors as lower-than-anticipated investment returns, inadequate employer contributions, and employee benefit increases, Illinois's pension plan was underfunded by approximately $95 billion in 2013 (Pew Center on the States, 2013). As a result, an increasing percentage of taxpayer dollars has been dedicated to paying pension obligations. Recent estimates suggest that roughly 20 percent of all tax dollars go toward paying pension costs (Pew Center on the States, 2013).

The issue of unfunded pension liabilities is not confined to the United States. Given the global nature of today's economic markets, a number of countries worldwide are also facing challenges in meeting their long-term pension obligations. An analysis of pension underfunding by the OECD found that while some countries, such as Canada and Sweden, possess financial reserves that exceed their liabilities, others, including the United Kingdom and Australia, face underfunding at levels comparable to US state and local government employers (Ponds et al., 2011).

For governments, both nationally and internationally, facing the challenge of resolving unfunded pension liabilities, there has been a growing push for compensation reform rooted not in earlier performance-related goals but in the perceived inability of public employers to maintain nonwage benefit packages at levels that have historically been provided. These financially driven reforms have taken a number of approaches to driving down retirement costs, but most focus on substantially reducing benefits afforded to current and future employees through such initiatives as increasing retirement eligibility age levels, increasing employee contributions to pension funds, and, in more extreme cases, creating retirement benefit plans that incorporate aspects of defined-contribution plans. For example, facing a $13.4 billion pension liability, the State of Rhode Island enacted pension reforms in 2011 that raised the retirement eligibility age from sixty-two to sixty-seven and moved current and future state employees from a traditional defined-benefit plan to a reduced defined-retirement benefit and a newly added defined-contribution plan (Pew Center on the States, 2011). Under this new plan, guaranteed lifetime benefits were reduced by nearly 50 percent with the expectation that employees would be able to supplement their retirement earnings through managed investments in their defined-contribution plan.

The growing inability of many public employers to cover their long-term pension liabilities will inevitably add fuel to the growing calls for benefit reforms such as the type enacted by the Rhode Island.

Challenges for Practice and Research

Public employers seeking to establish effective compensation systems capable of meeting their human capital needs face a number of critical challenges. First, it is safe to assume that despite their somewhat dismal record of success, efforts to enact performance-driven pay reforms will be a fact of life for practitioners at all levels of government. While policymakers and researchers should continue exploring the impact of existing reform efforts on employee attitudes and performance, Perry et al. (2009) astutely point out that future academic research should begin to address such topics as alternative designs for performance pay systems, the potential for more effective group incentive pay plans, unique cases or circumstances where performance pay has been successfully implemented, and alternative outcome measures for evaluating the success of such pay plans. Fostering research in these areas will greatly improve the field of public administration's understanding of performance-driven reform efforts and increase the likelihood of their successful implementation in the future.

Another major challenge relates to the need to continually assess wage competitiveness while also accounting for the short- and long-term impact of fiscally driven compensation reforms on core employment metrics such as employee recruitment and retention. There have been increasing calls for public employers to follow benefit trends in the private sector by transitioning from defined-benefit to defined-contribution plans. While there has not been a wholesale move to such plans in the public sector, the increasing challenge that public employers face in paying existing and future retiree benefits will inevitably push more public employers to consider these types of fiscally driven reform initiatives. However, unlike performance-driven reforms, fiscally based efforts to transform nonwage benefits hold the potential to significantly alter the historical balance in public sector compensation where perceived below-market wage rates have been offset by relatively generous, nonportable retirement benefits.

Transitioning to defined-contribution retirement plans will most likely result in two immediate outcomes. First, it will place greater emphasis on the competitiveness of public sector wage rates since the robustness of retirement savings under defined-contribution plans is directly related to the percentage of an employee's salary that can be contributed to the plan. The longstanding acceptance of perceived below-market wage rates for public sector employees, however, will inevitably serve as an impediment for public employers seeking to remain competitive in the broader labor market. Second, it will place a greater emphasis on employee retention efforts since a hallmark of defined-contribution plans is their portability from employer to employer. While defined-benefit plans have rewarded employee tenure, resulting in higher retention rates, defined-contribution plans reward individual contributions to retirement accounts and sound investing decisions by employees. While the implications for practice are somewhat clear, there has been relatively little analysis of the short- and long-term human capital implications for transitioning away from traditional defined-benefit programs. Future research will need to address this gap by assessing how fiscally driven reforms affect core employment indicators such as job satisfaction and employee turnover and by identifying cases where public employers have successfully maintained their human capital following substantial benefit reforms.

Practical Guidance for Public Managers and Policymakers

Research and current practices in public sector compensation suggest a number of key strategies for public managers and policymakers with regard to crafting effective compensation practices. One promising alternative to merit pay reforms is the use of nonmonetary employee rewards. Recent experimental research in the field of behavioral economics has shown that nonmonetary rewards, such as recognition ceremonies for outstanding contributions, can significantly increase employee motivation (Neckermann & Frey, 2013), in some cases just as much monetary rewards do (Ashraf, Bandiera, & Jack, 2014). While many public employers support such efforts within their current performance recognition processes, it can be asserted that nonmonetary awards policies have not been viewed as a viable alternative to conventional merit pay policies and thus have not been robustly pursued as a means of strategically increasing employee and organizational performance. In light of their cost-effectiveness and the growing recognition of their capacity to motivate employees, especially those with high levels of intrinsic motivation, it would be prudent for public managers and policymakers to pursue such options. This strategy for increasing employee performance is even more attractive considering the fiscal state of many public employers.

A second strategy involves strategic changes to the design and implementation of traditional compensation and classification systems. Research has highlighted the difficulties of implementing merit pay and pay-banding systems due to their significant departure from traditional seniority-based grade-level systems. A compromise approach to retaining the structure of traditional systems while also providing the flexibility of reformed systems could entail a combination of such policies as expanding salary ranges within grade-level systems, introducing additional grades, or creating more tailored classification systems.

Recent suggestions for improving the US federal government's classification and compensation system are grounded in these potential strategies. For example, there is an approximate 30 percent range between minimum and maximum wage rates within GS grade levels; expanding this range to 40 or 50 percent would significantly relieve salary compression and allow more externally competitive wage rates (Perry & Buckwalter, 2010; Condrey, Facer, & Llorens, 2012 2013). In addition, the federal government's GS classification and compensation system relies on a one-size-fits-all approach to compensating both lower–graded positions and higher-graded professional positions. Despite research by the Bureau of Labor Statistics showing that the relative pay of entry-level and senior-level GS employees varies considerably, with lower-graded employees enjoying wage premiums and high-graded positions enjoying wage penalties compared to their private sector counterparts, the federal government continues to adjust salaries across the board without accounting for broader differences in compensation. This shortcoming could be addressed by simply changing the current regulatory process to allow wage adjustments by grade level, which would enable targeted pay adjustments to only grade levels that are found to possess below-market wage rates (Condrey et al., 2012 2013).

A third strategy relates to a renewed focus on the public service benefits of working in the public sector. While public employers have historically been able to supplement relatively low wage rates by offering job candidates the promise of generous, guaranteed retirement benefits, this will most likely not be the case moving forward. As a result, public employers seeking to remain competitive in the broader labor market will need to develop and implement recruitment strategies that frame public job opportunities as public service opportunities, not simply generic means of stable employment (Perry et al., 2009; Perry and Buckwalter, 2010). While this task may be less difficult for occupations that are clearly rooted in public service (e.g., a foreign service officer or firefighter), it will be a greater challenge to do so for jobs with direct counterparts in the private sector (e.g., an accountant). Some public employers are already meeting this challenge and stand out as examples for other employers. As the US federal government's tax collector, one would not immediately think of the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) as a first choice for those seeking to fulfill their public service motivation. Yet despite this obvious shortcoming in its public perception, the IRS has successfully linked its core tax collection efforts to other activities more commonly associated with public service. For instance, in its career literature, it asserts that its tax collection efforts are critical to “securing the nation and protecting social services” and to “maintaining parklands and forests, building libraries, opening museums, enhancing schools and much, much more” (US Internal Revenue Service, 2014). Such efforts to connect seemingly unrelated occupations to essential public service activities stand out as clear examples for the public sector as a whole.

Summary

This chapter has looked at some of the more pressing challenges in contemporary public sector compensation and has highlighted how these challenges have been influenced by the unique environmental context that public compensation systems operate within. While traditional compensation systems have been effective at establishing internal wage equity and limiting the presence of favoritism, patronage, and discrimination in the workplace, they have generally been perceived as falling short in their ability to reward individuals and encourage high performance. Merit pay and pay-banding reforms have sought to address these shortcomings, but evidence from research and practice continues to highlight their incompatibility with public compensation systems and inability to significantly improve employee performance. Related to the challenge of effectively rewarding individual employees, there has been a growing debate over the overall competitiveness of public sector wage rates, and this issue has grown in importance as governments seek to scale back public sector retirement benefits to address unfunded pension liabilities. For governments seeking to adopt more wage-based, defined-contribution retirement plans, the overall competitiveness of their wages will become a critical factor in maintaining their human capital capacity.

A number of strategic steps can be taken to ensure the continued effectiveness of public sector compensation systems. First, public managers should devote more time and resources to crafting nonmonetary rewards strategies. Second, policymakers should seek to adjust traditional compensation policies to allow increased wage growth opportunities without giving up the benefits of such systems in terms of fairness and equity. Last, and most important, policymakers and public managers should bolster their efforts to focus on the public service benefits of public employment. It is highly unlikely that the public sector will ever match the private sector in terms of its compensation practices, but the opportunity to affect lives and serve the public good will remain one of the critical assets of public employment.

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset