CHAPTER 8
Inflation
When What You Get Isn’t What You Expect

INTRODUCTION

One of the most persistent deviations between actual and expected outcomes since the financial crisis has been the behavior of inflation. A lack of inflation has been a ubiquitous problem among advanced economies since the global financial crisis, even as monetary policy has been pushed to what can only be considered as ultra-accommodative. With price stability one of the Federal Reserve’s goals mandated by Congress and the primary benchmark of success for other central banks, the dearth of inflation has presented a clear challenge for policy makers seeking to normalize interest rates and employ the traditional tools of monetary policy.

Prior to the financial crisis, central banks had established command over inflation. After stagflation in the 1970s, in which inflation flourished and the real economy languished, monetary policy makers established credibility in fighting inflation by adjusting interest rates. In recent years, however, with interest rates at record lows, inflation continues to run well below what models have predicted. Federal Reserve officials have been steadily nudging down medium-term inflation forecasts while standing pat that inflation will return to 2.0 percent over the longer run.

Policies aimed at stoking inflation back up to more palatable levels have fallen short all across the developed world. Record low interest rates, unprecedented expansion of the monetary base, and even a foray into negative interest rates have all failed to generate inflation in the way models predicted. Is this a case of the dynamic nature of price adjustments not being properly captured in models, or is the post–Great Recession inflation environment different from the past?

The deviation between the actual and expected path of inflation has consequences for consumers, businesses, investors, and policy makers. Any variance between the path of realized versus expected inflation alters the real rate of interest. The recent shortfall in inflation therefore has provided a relative benefit to savers (lenders), while adversely affecting borrowers who thought the real value of debt would be lower. For the Federal Reserve, the discrepancy between realized and expected inflation has led to an adjustment in the expected path of interest rates. In early 2012, Federal Reserve officials expected the fed funds target rate would be raised twice by the end of 2014, but the fed funds target rate was instead held at its record low until the end of 2015.

In this chapter, we review the importance of inflation for consumers, investors, and policy makers. If consistent with expectations, inflation should be neutral for economic actors. However, economic reality often varies from what is expected, and inflation is no different. To understand how inflation may deviate from expectations, we look at the historical drivers of inflation and how the post–Great Recession environment in many ways marks a departure from the past. We then turn to statistical methods that help us better understand how inflation may evolve in the future across the United States and other advanced economies.

WHAT IS INFLATION?

Inflation is the aggregate change in prices for goods and services within the economy. Over any period, prices for individual products are changing to reflect individual supply-and-demand dynamics. For example, a bumper crop of tomatoes one season may send prices for them lower, as the rise in supply exceeds the initial level of demand at the previous price. At the same time, drought may ravage cattle herds, sending prices for beef higher as supply falls. What matters for inflation, however, are not these individual price movements, but the overall fluctuation in prices when looking across the economy.

As consumers and businesses go about their purchases, the level cost of goods is what stands out. For example, between June 2014 and June 2015, the average price of a gallon of gas fell $0.89. Inflation, however, is viewed as the rate of change in the price level, that is, the percent change in prices over a given period. Therefore, whether prices stabilize at historically high or low levels does not have a bearing on inflation, so long as prices stabilize, since the rate of change would be zero.

The term inflation is broadly applied to describe how prices change in the economy. More specifically, however, inflation refers to a rise in prices over time. Deflation, on the other hand, refers to a decline in prices over time. Between the spectrum of inflation and deflation is disinflation, which denotes an increase in overall price levels, but at a slower rate. For example, when the annual rate of inflation slowed from 1.8 percent to 0.2 percent from 2014 to 2015 following the collapse in oil prices, the economy experienced a bout of disinflation, but not deflation, as the aggregate price level did not decline (Figure 8.1). Hyperinflation is an extreme inflationary scenario, where prices rise extraordinarily fast, even exponentially.

Graph shows curve for PCE deflator during the period 2000 to 2016 which is nearly one percentage with steep decline between 2009 and 2010.

Figure 8.1 PCE Deflator

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

WHY DOES INFLATION MATTER?

For anyone trying to save money for a future purchase, inflation may seem undesirable. With the cost of goods and services generally rising over time, the purchase is likely to cost more in the future than it does today. In other words, inflation erodes the value of money over time. Therefore, it may seem odd that central bankers actually want inflation, rather than try to keep prices stable over time.

While for savers the positive rate of inflation may be unwelcome, the alternative of deflation is significantly more dangerous for the economy. If consumers see prices falling on a sustained basis, they will begin to hold back their spending. As they hold back their spending, aggregate demand falls further, leading to even lower prices in order for the market to clear. At the same time, businesses postpone investment, as investment will be cheaper in the future. The combined effects lead to a collapse in growth, as was seen during the Great Depression.

In addition to holding back spending and investment, deflation makes deleveraging more difficult for debtors. As aggregate prices decline, workers will receive less income, businesses will receive less revenue, and governments will receive less tax revenue, all else being equal. As a result, the fixed amount of debt owed becomes more burdensome to repay as the real value of their debt rises. The result can be defaults, which negatively impact both borrower and lender but also lead to a greater share of income being devoted to debt rather than current consumption, which can help support overall demand.

Why, then, do central bankers not simply aim for a zero rate of inflation? Monetary policy is a blunt instrument. Inflation can fluctuate significantly around policy makers’ objectives. Developments outside their control can lead to significant price changes in some items and overall inflation levels. The 2014–2016 collapse in oil prices offers an example, as the political decision among Organization of the Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) members not to cut production was a major factor in driving prices lower. Floods and droughts are other examples of how prices can also be affected by factors outside monetary policy makers’ control and keep inflation from running at its target for a period of time. Yet even among specific episodes that clearly impact inflation, inflation is difficult to fine-tune. The post–Great Recession environment offers a good illustration, where despite historically accommodative monetary policy, inflation fell short of the Federal Reserve’s goal for the better part of seven years (Figure 8.2).

Graph shows curves for PCE deflator and core PCE deflator during the period 1992 to 2016. The constant line at two percentage represents FOMC's two percentage inflation target.

Figure 8.2 PCE Deflator vs. Core PCE Deflator

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

Therefore, policy makers prefer to have some cushion between the target rate inflation and deflation, as the negative effects of modest inflation are significantly smaller than the costs of slipping into a deflationary spiral. For example, the Federal Reserve, Bank of England, and Bank of Japan all have inflation targets of 2.0 percent, while the European Central Bank and Swiss National Bank target inflation at less than 2 percent. Other major central banks may aim for slightly higher inflation (Norges Bank of Norway at 2.5 percent, Bank of Mexico at 3 percent) or a target range, as seen in Canada (2.0 percent +/– 1.0 percent) and Australia (2.0 to 3.0 percent).

Ultimately, the impact of inflation depends on the realized rate of inflation versus what was expected. If households and businesses expect 2 percent inflation and incorporate that into their wage demands, selling prices, and decisions to take out debt and investment plans, then an actual inflation rate of 2 percent would be neutral on their real finances.

In other words, realized inflation, and inflation expectations and forecasts in particular, play a central role at every level of decision making for economic agents. Households, businesses, and governments and policy makers all must factor in assumptions about future inflation into their spending and investment decisions. Households must consider future inflation when negotiating wages, taking on debt at a given nominal interest rate, and choosing how to direct savings into investments. The expected rate of inflation is a critical input to many key business decisions, including planning for wage and salary increases, adjusting rents and budgeting for facilities maintenance and upkeep. Governments must take into account future inflation when estimating revenues and outlays, particularly when those outlays may extend well into the future.

Inflation forecasts influence investment and budget planning both directly and indirectly. A higher inflation forecast suggests more monetary (nominal) funds will be needed to purchase resources or complete tasks. Since nearly all organizations, public, private, and nonprofit, operate with limited funds, an accurate inflation forecast is critical in order to properly allocate resources. For instance, a higher inflation forecast suggests that a larger sum of monetary resources is required to complete a task compared to the past, all else being equal. If actual inflation comes in at a lower level than the forecast had predicted, decision makers will have overestimated costs, meaning they may have missed the opportunity to acquire certain materials or assets and/or complete certain tasks. Inflation forecasts also indirectly influence investment and budgetary decisions via interest rates. Investment and budget planning relies on careful consideration of borrowing costs, as higher (or lower) expected borrowing costs would greatly influence many business decisions. Therefore, inflation rates (particularly inflation forecasts) are essential elements of decision making for economic agents.

The expected rate of inflation is also important for monetary policy makers who aim to keep inflation running at a moderate rate in order to help facilitate an appropriate rate of growth for the economy. The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) takes into account the forecast for inflation when forming monetary policy decisions. Monetary policy works with a lag, and therefore policy makers must be particularly mindful not only of the current rate of inflation but how inflation is likely to evolve over the medium term, which is typically considered about two to three years.

Furthermore, private-sector forecasters, including many members of the Blue Chip Economic Indicators group, believe that the FOMC will change the stance of monetary policy if the economy/inflation moves in a different direction than the Fed’s forecast. Some observers believe that the Fed has more information or more accurate forecasts than private forecasters, and therefore the forecasts of policy makers provide signals about the future path of policy. In addition, private forecasters may modify their forecasts according to the signals provided by the Fed’s forecasts. Put differently, inflation forecasts from the FOMC, to some extent, set inflation expectations as well as expectations for the overall economy.

WHAT DETERMINES INFLATION?

While economists are in agreement as to why inflation matters, there is somewhat less consensus around the drivers of inflation. There are several theories of inflation, and each theory suggests somewhat different drivers of inflation. The different theories exist since, over time, the magnitude of the association between different variables has fluctuated as the economy has evolved. In addition, some inflation drivers may be more influential in the short run and other drivers more impactful on long-run inflation, with different theories focusing on different time horizons for inflation. Over the years, however, different theories of inflation have fallen in and out of favor depending on how adequately they fit with the current inflationary environment.

Quantity Theory of Money

The money supply is one of the key drivers of inflation rates, as suggested by the quantity theory of money. That is, the quantity theory of money postulates that the money supply has a positive (direct), proportional relationship with the inflation rate. Put differently, ceteris paribus, a 1 percent increase in growth of money supply would increase inflation rate by 1 percent. The magnitude of the relationship between the money supply and inflation may vary (depending on phases of the business cycle along with other factors), but the relationship between the two variables is well established in the literature.

Interest rates also play a role in driving inflation. Imbedded within the nominal interest rates is an inflation component. As described in the Fisher equation, the nominal interest rate is equal to the real inflation rate plus inflation.

numbered Display Equation

Since interest rates are the cost of holding money, interest rates (nominal interest rates in particular) influence the demand for money. From the quantity theory of money we know that the money supply also influences prices and therefore inflation may have a two-way causal relationship with interest rates. Higher inflation expectations may therefore boost nominal interest rates because the FOMC would be expected to raise the fed funds rate to control inflation. Therefore, in theory, there is a link between money supply/demand, interest rates, and the inflation rate.

A Phillips Curve Framework

The money supply and interest rates alone, however, do not determine inflation. Other factors, such as aggregate demand, can affect the strength of the relationship between the monetary base, interest rates, and inflation. A practical example is the U.S. economy following the Great Recession. The FOMC increased the money supply significantly. Between late 2008 and mid-2014, the monetary base expanded by more than $2.5 trillion as the Federal Reserve embarked on three rounds of asset purchases, or quantitative easing. Over the same period, the fed funds target rate was left at 0 to 0.25 percent from December 2008 to December 2015. The inflation rate, however, continued to register significantly below the FOMC’s target of 2 percent. The average rate of inflation from 2009 to 2014 was just 1.4 percent, as measured by the PCE deflator.

The post–Great Recession environment runs contrary to the quantity theory of money as well as Milton Friedman’s statement that inflation is a monetary phenomenon. A possible justification of the broken link between the inflation and monetary variables is lack of aggregate demand. That is, following the 2007–2009 recession, the economy’s recovery was painfully slow. While the economy began to grow again in mid-2009, the pace was well below its historic average. In addition, slack in the labor market persisted, with full employment not being reached for another seven years. Demand remained weak as credit growth slowed and households and businesses deleveraged, leading to a slower velocity of money.

The impact of aggregate demand on inflation is typically explained through the Phillips curve framework. The Phillips curve suggests a relationship between the unemployment rate—a proxy for demand in the economy—and wages and inflation. The unemployment rate is inversely correlated with inflation. Greater demand drives lower unemployment, and as excess resources in the economy, in this case labor, are absorbed, prices move higher. This relationship between stronger demand and higher prices is referred to as demand-pull inflation. With more workers earning higher wages, aggregate spending increases, pulling up prices as “too much spending follows too few goods.” Therefore, at least in the short run, the effectiveness of money supply and interest rates as inflation drivers may depend on the aggregate demand.

Throughout history, the strength in the link between inflation and the unemployment rate has varied. After Arthur Phillips first published work on the link between unemployment and wages in the United Kingdom in 1958, economists Paul Samuelson and Robert Solow found a similar relationship in the United States between unemployment and inflation.1 However, the link seemed to break down in the 1970s, when both inflation and unemployment in the United States soared (Figure 8.3).

Graph shows curves for average hourly wages and unemployment during the period 1965 to 2015. Average hourly wages and unemployment are maximum between 1980 and 1985.

Figure 8.3 Unemployment and Wage Growth

Source: U.S. Department of Labor

The breakdown highlighted how the trade-off between lower unemployment and inflation was only a short-run phenomenon and excluded supply shocks. Policy makers could boost aggregate demand in the short run, leading to temporarily higher inflation, but actual inflation also depends on expected inflation. If economic agents expect higher inflation, then for a given level of unemployment, inflation becomes higher. The inclusion of inflation expectations is known as the augmented Phillips curve and can be written as follows:

numbered Display Equation

where π is inflation, uun is the difference between the actual and estimated natural rate of unemployment, and β measures how sensitive inflation is to unemployment. The term π–1 illustrates that current inflation depends in part on recent inflation, as recent inflation affects inflation expectations and therefore price setting, wage demands, spending, and so on. Shocks, such as the oil price collapse in 2014–2016, also influence inflation and are represented by the term v.

More recently, the unemployment rate in the United States has fallen from a peak of 10 percent following the recession to less than 5 percent. Yet inflation has been little changed, leading some to question the efficacy of the Phillips curve. Stable and relatively low inflation expectations in recent years in part explain why actual inflation has remained so low in the Phillips curve framework. However, even when accounting for inflation expectations, the relationship between unemployment and wages/inflation has diminished (i.e., the slope of the Phillips curve has declined), although the relationship is still found to be present.2

Moreover, the relationship between unemployment and wages/inflation depends on the economy being at full employment. If the economy is not yet at full employment, then excess labor reduces the need for employers to raise wages. This leads to the idea of the nonaccelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU), also known as the natural rate of unemployment. Stronger demand would not be expected to drive inflation higher until unemployment has reached its natural rate. Estimates of the natural rate of unemployment vary over time as structural factors in the economy change (Figure 8.4). In recent years, Federal Reserve officials and the Congressional Budget Office estimate the natural rate of unemployment at around 4.8 percent. Through the first half of 2016, the unemployment rate averaged 4.9 percent, suggesting wage and broader inflationary pressure would only now begin to be building in the post-recession environment.

Graph shows curves for natural rate in first quarter and unemployment rate in second quarter during the period 1980 to 2016. The unemployment rate decline from 1980 to 2008.

Figure 8.4 Unemployment Rate and NAIRU

Sources: U.S. Department of Labor and Congressional Budget Office

Cost-Push Inflation

In addition to demand, supply side shocks can also alter inflation, particularly in the short run. Sharp reductions in the supply common products can send price higher, raising overall inflation. This scenario is known as “cost-push” inflation. The most well-known example of this situation is the oil crisis of the 1970s. In retaliation for supporting Israel in the 1973 Arab-Israeli war, OPEC members placed an embargo on exports to the United States and other countries supporting Israel and also cut production. Between the middle of 1973 and the end of 1974, oil prices more than tripled. The rapid rise in energy costs sent overall inflation, as measured by the consumer price index (CPI), up from 3 percent in 1972 to 11 percent in 1974.

Cost-push inflation can also work the other way and lead to lower inflation. More recently, OPEC’s decision not to cut production to prop up prices amid rising North American supply sent shockwaves through the oil market. Oil prices fell around 75 percent from the middle of 2014 to early 2016. The lower cost of oil and related products pushed overall inflation lower, with the CPI briefly falling below zero. In addition to prices for energy goods falling, prices for transportation services also declined, pushing core goods prices lower, as it was cheaper to ship products.

Sometimes, past events (either demand-pull or cost-push) or expectations lead to inflationary pressures in an economy, which is referred to as built-in inflation. For example, a persistent demand-pull or cost-push scenario may increase inflation expectations and workers may push for higher wages in anticipation of higher inflation. In addition, producers may raise prices expecting higher input prices as well as higher wages.

Inflation Expectations

Recent inflation experiences can play an important role in expectations of future inflation. The inflation effects of short-term fluctuations in demand or supply previously discussed can shape how businesses and consumers think about future inflation. Following the 2014–2016 drop in oil prices, both market and consumer expectations for inflation fell. Given the significant role of energy prices on overall inflation, the decline in short-term inflation expectations reflected recent price movements. However, long-term inflation expectations (both market-based measures of compensation and consumer expectations) also fell to record lows (Figure 8.5). The drop in long-term expectations came even though oil prices could not fall forever and prices only needed to stabilize, let alone rise, for inflation—which, again, is the rate of change in prices, not a level—to move higher.

Graph shows curves for median inflation expectations for 5-10 years and fed 5-year five years forward, during the period 1999 to 2015. Median inflation expectations for 5-10 years is maximum between 2008 and 2009.

Figure 8.5 Median Inflation Expectations 5 to 10 Years Ahead

Sources: University of Michigan and Federal Reserve Board

The drop in the public’s inflation expectations may have in part been driven by the Federal Reserve’s own forecasts. As mentioned earlier, the FOMC publishes its forecast for key economic variables, including inflation, regularly and market participants (financial markets in particular) pay close attention to those forecasts. Inflation forecast from the FOMC play a role in shaping the inflation expectations among economic agents. For more than two years, the FOMC repeatedly cut its inflation forecasts for the 2016 core PCE deflator (Figure 8.6). The persistent cuts to the Fed’s own forecasts of future inflation, along with the recency bias of lower realized inflation, likely weighed on the public’s perception of future inflation. A simple ordinary least squares (OLS) regression of core inflation based on the unemployment rate gap (measured by the unemployment rate minus its estimated natural rate) and long-term inflation expectations shows inflation expectations play a significantly larger role in determining core inflation.

Graph shows curve for core PCE projections representing curve and its surrounding area.

Figure 8.6 2016 Core PCE Projections

Source: Federal Reserve Board

INFLATION AFTER THE GREAT RECESSION

The leading theories of inflation appear to do little to explain the post–Great Recession price environment. After more than seven years of expansion and a labor market near full employment, core inflation in the United States has remained stubbornly low. With the exception of a few months in early 2012, the core PCE deflator has continuously run below the Federal Reserve’s 2 percent target. Inflation measured by the core CPI has been somewhat stronger, as it often is due to its different methodology, but it too has proved weaker than many expected this far from the financial crisis.

The lack of inflation has come as a surprise to many, particularly those who follow the quantity theory of money. Central bankers around the world have embarked on extensive asset purchase programs, that is, quantitative easing (QE), in recent years with the aim of boosting inflation and lowering interest rates beyond main policy rates. Modeled after efforts made by the Bank of Japan back in 2001 to boost Japanese inflation, the Federal Reserve was the first major central bank to turn to QE following the global financial crisis (followed shortly by the Bank of England). Between three rounds of quantitative, nearly $4 trillion in assets were added to the Fed’s balance sheet (Figure 8.7), sparking fears of runaway inflation. Yet where was the inflation?

Graph shows curves for foreign swaps, PDCF and TAF, other, commercial paper and money market, repos and dis. window, agencies and MBS and treasuries during the period 2007 to 2016.

Figure 8.7 Federal Reserve Balance Sheet

Source: Federal Reserve Board

What the monetarist adherents of inflation failed to take into account were the dynamics beyond the money supply. While ceteris paribus, a multitrillion-dollar increase in the money supply would spur inflation, all was not equal. Aggregate demand in the economy remained far weaker than in previous expansions and slower than even downgraded estimates of potential growth. The Congressional Budget Office estimated that the output gap, the difference between potential output and actual economic output, at one point reached more than $1 trillion and has yet to fully close (Figure 8.8). The lingering slack in the economy led to little inflationary pressure despite the massive increase in the Fed’s balance sheet and money supply.

Graph shows curves for potential GDP and actual GDP in first quarter during the period 2000 to 2016. Actual GDP decline between 2009 and 2010.

Figure 8.8 U.S. Output Gap

Sources: Congressional Budget Office and U.S. Department of Commerce

Also underappreciated was the potential for an altered transmission mechanism between the Fed’s balance sheet and overall credit growth in the post-crisis environment. The weak growth backdrop limited both the demand and supply of new credit. Perhaps more important was the new regulatory environment. The emergence of new capital requirements contributed to banks’ desire to be more cautious in credit expansion following the financial crisis. Additionally, new liquidity requirements led banks to increase their investment in safe, liquid assets, such as excess reserves held at central banks. The new rules, and even the anticipation of the changes, led to a different allocation of assets than would have been expected prior to the crisis, altering the course in which credit was expanded. Following QE, excess reserves at banks rose closely in line with the Fed’s balance sheet (Figure 8.9). The weaker transmission mechanism between money, credit, and growth led to a sharp slowdown in the velocity of money (Figure 8.10).

Graph shows curves for excess reserves and fed balance sheet during the period 2006 to 2016. Two curves are constant between 2006 and 2008 and increase afterward.

Figure 8.9 Excess Bank Reserves

Source: Federal Reserve Board

Graph shows curve for M2 velocity in first quarter for the duration 1960 to 2016 with highest peak at 1998 and decline afterward.

Figure 8.10 M2 Money Supply Velocity

Sources: Federal Reserve Board and U.S. Department of Commerce

Inflation Expectations and the Case of the Missing Deflation

Even as credit growth and broad demand have improved as the expansion has continued, inflation has remained stubbornly low. Yet this is not the first time in this cycle where inflation has been “stickier” than predicted by slack-based models. The rise in the unemployment rate to 10 percent and 4 percent decline in real gross domestic product (GDP) signaled a collapse in demand that should have also ushered in a collapse in prices, at least temporarily. However, core inflation slowed by only a little more than 1 percentage point and, despite the worst downturn since the Great Depression, remained around 1 percent. The mild weakening in inflation compared to what models predicted led economists on a search to explain the “missing deflation.”

The search has highlighted the importance of inflation expectations in determining realized inflation. While the unemployment rate more than doubled and hit nearly a 30-year high, long-term inflation expectations, measured by the University of Michigan’s Consumer Sentiment Survey, fell from an average of 3.1 percent in 2008 to 2.8 percent in 2010. Models including inflation expectations, and their relative stability in the downturn, better captured the behavior of inflation.3

Wages and Productivity in Inflation

As the expansion has proceeded and inflation has remained low, the modest rates of inflation now look to be altering consumer and business inflation expectations for the future. While the labor market has neared full employment and core inflation has improved, inflation expectations—both short and long term—began to slide from what were already low levels in late 2014.

The reduction in inflation expectations alters the path and intensity of future price and wage increases. Disappointing wage growth has been a common refrain since the recession. Explanations include the traditional slack arguments where, with the labor market only recently reaching levels that could be considered full employment, employers had little need to boost wages in order to attract or maintain workers. Research has also pointed to the stickiness of wages, where employees are reluctant to accept wage cuts. Therefore, even as slack rises, wages do not fall. In order for employers to adjust real wages, they therefore reduce the rate of future wage increases in what is referred to as pent-up wage cuts.4

However, the path of productivity plays an important role in the wage debate as well as its impact on inflation. Productivity is the ultimate driver of real wage gains as workers earn the marginal product of their labor. After an initial bump in 2009–2010 when demand began to rise again, yet employers were hesitant to hire, labor productivity slowed to a crawl, averaging just 0.5 percent per year from 2011 to 2016 (Figure 8.11). The weak rate of productivity growth along with low inflation was consistent with slow nominal wage growth.

Bar graph shows nonfarm labor productivity for two separate periods 1948 to 1973, 1974 to 1995, 1996 to 2003, 2004 to 2016 and 2004 to 2007, 2008 to 2010, 2011 to 2016.

Figure 8.11 Nonfarm Labor Productivity

Source: U.S. Department of Labor

If productivity remains weak, then diminishing slack in the labor market can more quickly lead to inflation as employers need to increase nominal wages faster than labor’s output. If workers are not producing more with each hour worked, raising topline revenues, employers cannot boost wages without cutting into margins or passing on higher labor costs through higher prices. The result is either a shift in income allocation from capital (profits) to labor, or inflation that offsets any nominal wage gains.

Recently, however, the link between labor costs and inflation has broken down more generally. The inability for employers to cut wages during the downturn (downward nominal wage rigidity) has been pointed to as one factor that kept inflation from falling as much as output-gap models would have suggested following the Great Recession. Yet the pass-through effects of higher wages and labor costs to inflation have weakened since the early 1980s, suggesting a diminished link between inflation and economic activity.5 The breakdown follows a declining share of income derived from labor earnings over the past few decades, weighed down by an aging population and falling labor force participation among prime-age workers (Figure 8.12).

Bar graph shows the breakdown of personal income sources for the parameters percentage of transfers, proprietor's income, rental income, supplement to wages, receipts on assets and wages and salary corresponding to 1980, 1990, 2000, 2010 and past 12 months.

Figure 8.12 Personal Income Sources

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

Not Going It Alone: Low Inflation Globally

The United States is not alone in its low-inflation experience. Around the world, many other advanced economies have struggled to bring inflation back up to rates consistent with central banks targets. In the Eurozone, where the European Central Bank aims to keep inflation under 2 percent, core consumer price inflation has hovered around 1 percent in recent years, while headline inflation has been near zero (Figure 8.13). In Sweden, inflation has been below the Riksbank’s target since 2012, while inflation in Switzerland has been well below 2 percent since the financial crisis (Figure 8.14).

Graph shows two curves for core CPI and CPI for the duration 1997 to 2015. CPI is maximum between 2007 and 2009 and core CPI is maximum at 2002.

Figure 8.13 Eurozone Consumer Price Inflation

Source: Eurostat

Graph shows two curves for core CPI and CPI for the duration 1997 to 2015. CPI is maximum between 2008 and 2009 and core CPI is maximum at 2009.

Figure 8.14 Swiss Consumer Price Index

Source: Swiss Federal Statistics Office

Japan has struggled most of all with low inflation. Prices have bordered on the brink between inflation and deflation for the past two decades, averaging just 0.1 percent per year. The inflation history of Japan highlights the challenges of persistently weak demand, exacerbated by unfavorable demographic trends. While Japan’s shrinking population makes the country’s demographic challenges more severe than any other major economy, other advanced economies, including the United States, face slower population growth and an aging population that portends slower growth and weaker inflation pressure.

The ubiquitous story of inflation running too low for the comfort of central banks follows the similarly common story of record monetary accommodation. Even as the Federal Reserve’s quantitative easing generated little help for inflation, it did not stop the European Central Bank from embarking on QE in early 2015 and for the Bank of Japan to further expand its balance sheet. QE was also undertaken with the aim to lower interest rates beyond central banks’ main policy rates. However, to further support inflation, a number of countries have lowered policy rates into negative territory, in the hopes of spurring credit growth and therefore demand in the economy. Less explicitly stated by central bankers is the currency effect of greater policy accommodation. As monetary policy eases, currencies depreciate amid capital outflows, all else being equal. The weaker currency can at least temporarily boost inflation via import prices. Yet, as evidenced with the inflation performance of the Eurozone, Sweden, and Japan, negative rates have done little to boost inflation.

The United States has been at the losing end of the currency/inflation dynamic. Even as the Federal Reserve has been slow to remove policy accommodation since the Great Recession, the relative strength of the U.S. economy has led to expectations that policy is more likely to tighten than ease, and is likely to tighten ahead of other major central banks. While the Fed has been talking about lifting rates, monetary policy in other advanced economies has become more accommodative or signaled that tighter policy would come at a later date than expected by the Fed. The divergence in policy and even the outlook for future policy caused the dollar to strengthen against a wide range of currencies. Between mid-2014 and the end of 2015, the broad trade-weighted dollar index strengthened more than 20 percent.

Lower import prices ensued. The strength in the dollar led to the effective cost of imported products falling as it took fewer dollars to purchase the same amount of foreign-denominated goods. Import prices for nonfuel items sank between autumn 2014 and the end of 2015 (Figure 8.15). Although the impact on overall consumer price inflation was limited since the majority of consumer spending is devoted to services, very few of which are imported, the stronger dollar contributed to weaker goods inflation. The CPI for goods excluding food and energy fell for the better part of 2013–2016, making it a drag on overall inflation (Figure 8.16).

Graph shows two curves of non-petroleum import prices and broad dollar index with steep decline between 2008 and 2009, for the duration 2000 to 2016.

Figure 8.15 Non-Petroleum Import Prices vs. Dollar

Source: U.S. Department of Labor and Federal Reserve Board

Core goods versus core services CPI graph shows curves of core services, core goods CPI and core CPI during the period 1988 to 2016. Core goods CPI decline at 2004.

Figure 8.16 Core Goods vs. Core Services CPI

Source: U.S. Department of Labor

The dollar is not the only factor, however, in weaker goods inflation. Globalization has opened up more markets, generating new sources of low-cost labor. Stronger productivity growth in manufacturing compared to services has also helped to reduce goods inflation in the United States and other economies.

Although inflation has not been as low as in advanced economies, developing countries have also experienced disinflation since the global financial crisis (Figure 8.17). At the forefront has been lower inflation in China. Consumer price inflation has slowed to around 2 percent after reaching 6 percent as recently as 2011. Overcapacity in the country’s industrial sector has led to the producer price index falling since 2012. The ongoing deflation in the “world’s factory” has contributed to lower goods inflation elsewhere in the world, via both cheaper prices for Chinese-made products, as well as tougher competition for foreign producers.

Graph shows curves for world consumer prices, OECD and emerging and developing during the period 2000 to 2016. OECD crosses zero line during the period 2009 to 2010.

Figure 8.17 World Consumer Price Inflation

Sources: International Monetary Fund and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development

The disinflationary trends over the past few years have been more welcome in many emerging markets, as inflation remains far from deflation territory. However, the similar trends in both advanced and developing countries highlight the weakness in demand globally since the recession, evidenced by global growth remaining under its long-run trend since 2012. Amid the slowdown, lower commodity prices have been a common theme across the world, but have played a larger role in developing nations since food and energy make up a larger share of consumer purchases.

APPLICATION: PREDICTING IF CENTRAL BANKS CAN ACHIEVE PRICE STABILITY

As we have discussed, inflation forecasts are a key input in many financial decisions, including interest rates, investments, budgets, and wage rates. Yet the recent inflation environment looks very different from the past. Traditional explanations for inflation, such as the quantity theory of money and the Phillips curve, no longer appear to explain price dynamics as successfully as they once did. As a result, the outlook for inflation has become more uncertain, with many wondering whether central banks will ever achieve their inflation goals.

To examine the path of future inflation in advanced economies and the global economy more broadly, we use an ordered probit approach to quantify the probability of disinflationary pressure in the future. We estimate the six-months-ahead probability of three distinct price scenarios: inflationary pressure, disinflationary/deflationary pressure, or price stability. Inflationary pressure can be viewed as inflation running above a central bank’s target. The disinflationary/deflationary scenario describes the likelihood that inflation would run well below target, while the price stability scenario can be described as the probability that inflation will be within or closely aligned with the target.

Although there is no single central bank for advanced economies, most target inflation to be around 2 percent. We therefore consider inflation of 1.5 to 2.5 percent to be consistent with price stability when looking at advanced economies. The probability of achieving price stability, however, has fallen since 2012, as has the likelihood of an inflation overshoot. Instead, it looks like the most likely price scenario for advanced economies is the continued undershoot of inflation, labeled as the “deflationary” scenario (Figure 8.18).

Graph shows curves for probability of deflationary pressure, probability of stable prices and probability of inflationary pressure during the period 1993 to 2015. Probability of deflationary pressure is in negative region and other two probability curves in positive region.

Figure 8.18 The Six-Months-Ahead Probability of Price Scenarios in Advanced Economies

Looking specifically at the advanced economies of the United States, Eurozone, and Japan paints a similarly bleak picture for central bankers aiming to revive inflation. The most likely outcome for U.S. economy is that inflation will remain stuck noticeably below the Fed’s 2.0 percent target, although the outlook for price stability looks marginally better than in 2015 (Figure 8.19). A similar story holds for the Eurozone, despite the efforts of the European Central Bank to stimulate credit growth and inflation since the Eurozone sovereign debt crisis (Figure 8.20). Even with the Bank of Japan’s herculean efforts to support inflation in recent years, returning inflation to around 2 percent remains a pipe dream (Figure 8.21).

Graph shows curves for probability of deflationary pressure, probability of stable prices and probability of inflationary pressure during the period 1984 to 2016. Probability of inflationary pressure is maximum at 1984 and decline afterward.

Figure 8.19 The Six-Months-Ahead Probability of Price Scenarios in the United States

Graph shows curves for probability of deflationary pressure, probability of stable prices and probability of inflationary pressure during the period 1997 to 2015. Probability of deflationary pressure decline between 2009 and 2010.

Figure 8.20 The Six-Months-Ahead Probability of Price Scenarios in the Eurozone

Graph shows curves for probability of deflationary pressure, probability of stable prices and probability of inflationary pressure during the period 1990 to 2016. Probability of inflationary pressure is constant at zero during 1998 to 2007 and 2009 to 2014.

Figure 8.21 The Six-Months-Ahead Probability of Price Scenarios in Japan

With so many major economies struggling to bring inflation back up to targeted levels, it is not surprising to see that inflation globally is expected to remain low by historical standards. Inflation in developing countries tends to run higher than advanced economies. From 1996 to 2014, global inflation averaged 4.4 percent per year, which we use as a benchmark for global “price stability” since there is no institution targeting global inflation. Our probit analysis finds that returning global inflation within half a percent of its long-term average is unlikely in the next six months. In fact, the likelihood that global inflation falls short of 3.9 percent is 100 percent (Figure 8.22). Such a high probability that global inflation will continue to run below its historic benchmark suggests a significant shift in the behavior of inflation over the past five years.

Graph shows curves for probability of deflationary pressure, probability of stable prices and probability of inflationary pressure during the period 1988 to 2016.

Figure 8.22 The Six-Months-Ahead Probability of Price Scenarios in the Global Economy

The likelihood that inflation will continue to fall short of policy makers’ goals and its long-run averages highlights how the inflation environment has changed since the recession. Low inflation is a new challenge to central bankers, who over the years have grown comfortable in their tools to combat excessive inflation. The low inflation environment has paved the way for record policy accommodation from central banks, whether through expanding balance sheets or negative interest rates. Determining the sources of inflation—or in recent years, the source of disinflation—is vital for decision makers since different sources may require distinct policy actions.

NOTES

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset