CHAPTER 6
Corporate Profits
Reward, Incentive, and That Standard of Living

For the engine that drives enterprise is not thrift, but profit.

—John Maynard Keynes

INTRODUCTION: PROFITS AS ESSENTIAL PARTNER

By autumn, something appeared amiss. While the equity markets soared, there was talk of rising interest rates and questions about the viability, as well as the momentum, of corporate profits going forward. There was an increased willingness to overlook traditional metrics and certainly the existence of a credit/profit cycle. But, of course, that was 1999 and investors had learned their lesson. Or had they?1

Our perspective is that there is a critical role of profits in economic growth in any economy and there is also a clear cycle in corporate profits within each economic recovery and over the long run. When those principles of cyclical variation are ignored, trouble usually follows. Now under way is our review of the historical patterns of profits over the business cycle.2 In this chapter, we examine the role of profits in our society and the many links profits have throughout our economy, including providing future income for retirees or other investors. To anticipate, there is a clear pattern of profits over the business cycle, and, contrary to many critics, profits are an essential partner in the success of the overall economy.

Profits are frequently disparaged in our society. However, profits, in many forms, drive a large part of economic activity. We often find that a political candidate “profits” from another candidate’s mistakes. Each year, many college football athletes will profit from hard work and a bit of luck with an opportunity to play in the NFL. A writer profits from her efforts and imagination by writing a best seller. Hollywood writers, producers, and actors profit from their efforts and imagination.

Yet when profits accrue to a “corporation” through the efforts of its employees and the insight of its leaders, those profits are often disparaged. Moreover, the profits of the corporation do not accrue to the “corporation,” but instead benefit its employees and investors—often in the form of pension plans for households and charitable contributions to their communities.

Profitable companies find many ways to contribute to their communities. Bankrupt firms do not. Profitable firms pay taxes. Bankrupt firms do not. The failure to appreciate the role of profits as a reward, incentive, and a fundamental building block for the standard of living for savers and investors and their many goals—including retirement—is a sad commentary in today’s public rhetoric.

THE ROLE OF PROFITS IN THE ECONOMIC CYCLE: FIVE DRIVERS

When viewed from the context of the business cycle, profits are a residual, or a buffer to fluctuations in the economy. Relative to real factors such as economic growth and employment, as well as inflation and wages, profits are more variable, as illustrated in Figure 6.1

Graph shows curves for corporate profits in third quarter and nominal GDP in fourth quarter during the period 1980 to 2016. Corporate profits with highest peak at 2010.

Figure 6.1 Corporate Profits before Taxes and Nominal GDP

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

What accounts for this variability? Profits reflect the effects of cyclical and exogenous forces. Since the timing of these forces is random, profit volatility is a natural outcome. Five factors dominate the pattern of profits. First, profits tend to follow the gap between actual output and potential output in the economy. The key issue here is fixed costs and idle capacity. When the economy is strong, actual output is close to capacity and firms are using their replete complement of capital and fixed resources, so the fixed cost per unit of output is low and thereby the firm is making efficient application of its land, equipment, and labor (Figure 6.2). However, when the economy is weak, per-unit fixed costs are higher due to more under- or unutilized physical capital; this is simply the concept of operating leverage for a company on a macro scale. In addition, there will be less work for an existing workforce, and this is associated with lower productivity and/or lower employment.

Graph shows curves for nonfinancial corporate profits in third quarter and capacity utilization in first quarter during the period 1982 to 2015, with steep decline at 2009.

Figure 6.2 Nonfinancial Corporate Profits vs. Capacity Utilization

Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce and Federal Reserve Board

Second, there is the cyclical pattern between output prices and input costs for many firms, which is shown in the comparison between output prices (as measured by the gross domestic product [GDP] deflator) and input prices, proxied by unit labor costs (Figure 6.3).3 Both series tend to move with the business cycle. A weak economy is associated with weak aggregate demand and weaker output prices relative to trend; thereby profit growth is weaker when compared to a stronger economy. In Figure 6.3, the rise in output prices tends to be faster than the increase in unit labor costs in the early years of the economic recovery (1983–1984, 1992–1995, 2002–2006, and 2009–2010) and thereby tends to boost profits in the early recovery period. However, as the economic expansion ages, unit labor costs catch up (1986–1988, 1997–1998, 2007, and 2012–2014) such that profit growth tends to slow.

GDP deflator versus unit labor costs graph shows two curves for unit labor costs and GDP deflator in fourth quarter, during the period 1982 to 2015. Unit labor costs shows steep decline at 2002 and 2010.

Figure 6.3 GDP Deflator vs. Unit Labor Costs

Sources: U.S. Departments of Commerce and Labor

Third, interest rates tend to fluctuate over the business cycle such that interest expense tends to be low in the early phase of an economic recovery as the Federal Reserve keeps rates low to boost economic growth, while during boom periods the Fed will tend to raise rates. In addition, during boom periods, the financial markets will reinforce the upward trend on interest rates to compensate for higher inflation and rising credit demand in a search for financing that usually accompanies the latter phases of the economic cycle. Furthermore, credit spreads often widen late cycle, exacerbating this phenomenon.

To complicate the cyclical factors, two exogenous factors are also at work. Energy price shocks have had a significant impact on aggregate demand and input costs. Changes in fiscal policy can alter the after-tax profits independent of the current stage of the economy.

THE ROLE OF PROFITS: INCENTIVES AND REWARDS

Profits are the returns on investment and are a prime motivating factor in the economy. Past profits and anticipated future profits directly affect business actions such as capital expenditures and hiring workers. Profits have three interesting roles in economic activity. First, profits act as a reward for entrepreneurship and innovation, as evidenced in the fortunes that accrued to innovators such as Thomas Edison, Henry Ford, Andrew Carnegie, John D. Rockefeller, Steve Jobs, Larry Page, Sergey Brin, Jeff Bezos, Bill Gates, and Paul Allen.

Second, profits act as an incentive to invest and speculate on the possibility of above-market returns. Higher anticipated future returns prompted individuals to invest in the auto and radio industries in the first half of the twentieth century and in consumer services such as department stores and fast food after WWII. In recent years, consumers have invested in technology, specifically technology focused on processing and communicating information—such as the exercise of apps on mobile phones. Profits also served as an incentive for the establishment of the Virginia colony in American history.4

Finally, profits often serve as a key contributor to the rising values in savings and investment accounts that are employed by households to meet many financial goals, including home purchases, college education, and retirement funding. Although overlooked or simply not understood by many, profits are the key to the growing nest eggs that finance much of economic activity. Innovations such as mutual funds, individual retirement accounts (IRAs), pensions, and, more recently, exchange-traded funds (ETFs) gain value over time as profits grow. As illustrated in Figure 6.4, profits contribute to personal income through the receipts on assets, proprietors’ income (self-employed profits), and as a supplement to wages and salaries (via contributions to employee pensions and government social insurance).

Pie chart shows sources of personal income with percentages for the month January, 2016. Sources includes transfer receipts, receipts on assets, rental income, proprietors income, supplement to wages and salaries and wage and salary disbursements.

Figure 6.4 Personal Income Sources

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

Defining Terms: Economic Profits— A Return to People, Not Corporations

Profits are a form of income and accrue to someone—not a corporation. Although referred to as “corporate” profits, the actual flow of funds accrues to investors. Investors are often individuals invested in pensions and mutual funds, direct shareholders of a specific company stock, and the company’s workers, who receive additional compensation today or in the future (profit sharing). In addition, corporate profits are taxed and are therefore a source of government funding. Pretax profits less corporate tax payments equals after-tax profits, which are either retained or paid out as dividends—again a return on investment and risk taking to someone.

Providing Character to Profits over Time: Over the Cycle and Relative to Trend

How can we characterize profits to better analyze the economy and gather insights into future patterns of employment, investment, and personal income growth? Profits have a pervasive influence on economic activity so our development of a better understanding of the patterns of profit growth will aid in our decision making about the economy.

Economists often face complex time series, such as corporate profits, and yet are asked to provide understanding and forecasts of its behavior to noneconomists, especially investors. We raise three fundamental questions about U.S. corporate profit growth, which are also common and critical questions faced by economists in characterizing the behavior of any macroeconomic series. First, can we identify a long-run trend component for profit growth and thereby separate the cyclical component from the trend? That is, at any given phase of the business cycle, are we positioned for above-trend growth (boom) or below-trend growth (slowdown)? Second, how volatile is profit growth, and does this volatility obscure the message of average profit growth? Third, does profit growth over time exhibit a mean-reverting behavior? That is, do profits exhibit a tendency to return to some average growth rate?

U.S. corporate profit growth can serve as a case study to identify the properties of any time series. First, we look at the data, plotted earlier in Figure 6.1. This reveals the historical pattern of the series and helps to visually identify whether the series has a deterministic trend over time, any unusual outliers, or a volatile pattern that might obscure a trend. In the next step, we compare profit growth between subsamples. This would help to analyze profit behavior in different time periods.

Separating the Trend from the Cycle: Benchmarking Profit Growth over the Economic Cycle

How can we tell when profit growth is faster or slower than its underlying trend? This is a key question since the answer forms the basis for our understanding of an acceleration or deceleration in profits, and thereby the contribution of profits to income growth and investment spending. Periods of accelerating profit gains are associated with a pickup in personal income growth, financial asset prices, business investment, and hiring. Decelerating profit growth indicates a slower, possibly even contractionary, economic environment.

Our approach here utilizes the Hodrick-Prescott (H-P) filter technique that identifies the trend in an economic time series outside of the business cycle.5 Our results are presented in Figures 6.5 and 6.6. In Figure 6.5, nonfinancial profits as a share of nonfinancial output (NFC ratio) takes on a clear cyclical pattern as the share rises in the early phase of an economic recovery (1991–1996, 2003–2006) but declines when growth slows down or the economy is in a recession (1997–2001). In the expansion that began in late 2009, we again can see the pickup in the profit share. Meanwhile, the trend of the NFC ratio series has drifted upward since 2002 in contrast to a more cyclical pattern from 1982 to 2002.

Graph shows curves for log and HP trend of NFC ratio in second quarter, during the period 1982 to 2014. Log of NFC ratio shows steep decline during the year 2002.

Figure 6.5 Decomposing NFC Ratio

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

Graph shows curves for H-P trend and log of profits in second quarter, during the period 1982 to 2014. Both the curve shows a rising trend.

Figure 6.6 Decomposing Corporate Profits

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

In Figure 6.6, we illustrate the log form of profits and show that there is a clear uptrend in the level of profits as well as the cyclical property of profits around its long-term trend.6 This cyclical pattern around the trend sets up investment opportunities for investors, who may look for markets that represent value relative to trend. That is, below-trend profits during 1994–1995 set up an opportunity for investment returns when profits returned to trend.

Linear, Nonlinear: Characterizing the Trend

Figures 6.5 and 6.6 provide the initial evidence of the trend and cyclical patterns of corporate profits for the complete sample period of 1982–2014:Q2. We also divide profit growth and profit margins into period subsamples so that we can apply statistical tools on the series and characterize its behavior in each sample.

First, we test whether profit growth and profit margins contain a time trend. There are two types of trends—linear and nonlinear. A linear trend indicates a constant growth rate, while a nonlinear growth rate is variable (see Silvia et al., 2014, for more detail). One of the tripwires in financial thinking is that all relationships are linear, and linearity is at play in many spreadsheets when strategists and economists operate their models.

In Table 6.1, we examine the sample period of 1982–2014 and provide the results from an identification process, which results in the finding of no trend in the growth rate of profits, while there is evidence of a nonlinear trend in the NFC ratio. This was foreseen given that we saw a clear cyclical pattern around a trend that itself moves up and down and is more characteristic of a nonlinear, rather than linear, trend in Figure 6.5

Table 6.1 Results from Identification Process (1982–2014)

Profits (Year-over-Year) NFC Ratio
Mean Standard Deviation Stability Ratio Trend Mean Standard Deviation Stability Ratio Trend
1982-1989 7.46 13.52 181.2 No Trend 0.10 0.01 10.9 Nonlinear Trend
1990-2014 7.47 11.96 160.1 No Trend 0.11 0.02 20.4 Linear Trend
2007-2014 5.54 16.60 299.8 N/A-Short History 0.13 0.02 13.0 N/A-Short History
1982-2014 7.47 12.31 164.8 No Trend 0.11 0.02 19.3 Nonlinear Trend

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

Stability Ratio over Different Economic Cycles

In addition, Table 6.1 provides the results of calculations of the mean and standard deviation for each subsample since 1982 as well as for the complete sample period of 1982–2014. We do this to identify whether all subsamples have the same mean and standard deviation. Moreover, we calculate a stability ratio—standard deviation as percent of the mean—for each subsample and for the complete period. The stability ratio helps us to identify how profit growth varies by sample. A higher stability ratio indicates a more volatile series.

We find that U.S. corporate profit growth is mean reverting. A high degree of volatility in profits is evident, however, with a higher standard deviation (12.31 percent) than the mean (7.47 percent). Finally, among the subsamples, the 1990–2014 period is more stable in terms of profit growth (lowest stability ratio) and the subsample since the Great Recession (2007–2014) contains the most volatile profit growth rates. The H-P filter reveals that profit growth was higher than its long-run trend growth during the 2003–2006 period, indicating an above-trend (and unsustainable?) pace of profit growth.

Results in Table 6.1 indicate that the average growth in profits since 1982 is remarkably stable at around 7.47 percent, with a standard deviation of 12.31 and a stability ratio of 164.8. However, once we isolate the 2007–2014 period, there is a clear break in the mean growth rate of profits which would be anticipated given the Great Recession in that period. In this case, the standard deviation is also larger than the mean, and as a result the stability ratio is also high. Contrary to popular commentary, profit growth has not picked up in recent years; rather, it has slowed in the most recent period.

For the NFC ratio, there is also remarkable stability in the mean value as well as in its standard deviation. For this ratio, there does not appear to be a significant break with the past for the 2007–2014 period.

Mean Reversion: Key Benchmark for Pursuing Accurate Analysis

Does the rate of growth in profits tend to revert to a mean value over time? This is a critical issue. First, effective statistical analysis requires that an economic series does not exhibit any trend (nonstationary). Second, if profit growth tends to rise continuously (or fall continuously), there are significant consequences for the overall economy. In a similar way, do profits as a percent of nonfinancial sector output also rise or fall over time?

After applying simple statistical tools, we move to the more sophisticated econometric technique of unit root testing. We apply an Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) unit root test on profit growth. The ADF unit root test was introduced by Dickey and Fuller (1979, 1981) and has the null hypothesis of a unit root, with the alternative that the series is stationary.7 If a series contains a unit root, we call it nonstationary; if not, it is stationary. A stationary series fluctuates around a constant long-run mean that implies that the series, profit growth in this case, has a finite variance that does not depend on time; hence, it is mean reverting.

In Table 6.2, the results for a test of mean reversion (stationarity) are presented. For the rate of growth of profits, the series is stationary (mean reverting) over the 1982–2014 period, and therefore can be utilized in statistical analysis. Unfortunately, the series for nonfinancial profits as a percent of nonfinancial output is nonstationary, and therefore must be transformed into a series that would be applicable in further statistical analysis.

Table 6.2 1982-2014 Profits and NFC Ratio Results

Profits (Year-over-Year) NFC-Ratio
Testing for Stationary
Stationary (Mean Reverting) Nonstationary
Identifying a Structural Break Using the State-Space Approach
Break Date Type of Break Coefficient Break Date Type of Break Coefficient
Q4-09 Additive 34.5867* Q2-08 Additive 0.015*
Q4-08 Additive −21.606* Q1-11 Additive −0.014*
Q1-83 Shift 9.32* Q4-01 Additive −0.014*
Q1-14 Additive −0.012*
Q2-05 Additive −0.011*

*Significant at 1 percent

A common practice is to utilize the mean of a series for decision making, which is naïve, in our view, as average values may not be constant over time. We provide a more accurate framework to analyze a variable of interest for decision making, that is, whether we should utilize the mean for decision making. In addition, the proposed framework is easy to apply, as an analyst can perform statistical tests using Excel and any standard statistical software. First, plot the series to learn about overall behavior. Then the mean, standard deviation, and stability ratio can be calculated for different business cycles to examine variation in these statistics between business cycles. The H-P filter helps to determine current behavior of the series relative to the long-run trend. The ADF test is a more appropriate method to determine whether the long-run average is practical in decision making. For instance, profit growth is mean reverting in our sample period, implying that any deviations from the 7.5 percent average are temporary in nature, statistically speaking.

Structural Break: History Discontinued

Naturally, there is an interest in knowing whether profit growth or the NFC ratio contained a structural break during the 1982–2014 period. The results in Table 6.2 indicate that there were no structural breaks in either series.8

We employ the State-Space approach to identify structural changes in the profits series. The approach identifies the change based on the chi-square test. In the present case, the chi-square test determined the five largest breaks in the profits series using the 0.01 level of significance. The null hypothesis is that the underlying variable does not contain a change and the alternative hypothesis is that there is a change in the behavior of the variable during the specified time period. After we are aware of the existence of a break, the State-Space approach would then determine the break date and the nature of the change (e.g., level shift, additive outlier, or temporary change).

Although we are only interested in level shifts (structural breaks), the other forms of breaks in a series are additive outliers and temporary changes. Identifying a level shift demonstrates that a variable has two or more “structures.” Thus, the data set can be divided into multiple subsamples depending on the number of breaks, and each subsample will have statistically significant differences in the descriptive statistics (e.g., mean and standard deviations). An additive outlier indicates that an observation is just that, an outlier in the data set. A temporary change, however, identifies a fixed duration of change in a variable before the variable returns to the previous level. For example, the GDP growth rate will turn negative during a recession, but then returns to positive territory once the recession ends. Where a temporary change is often the result of the business cycle, a structural shift is often due to a change in policy or a more fundamental economic change.

Summing up, profits, as a return to entrepreneurship and real capital investment, play a crucial role as both incentives and rewards in our economic system. While profits are frequently disparaged by many commentators, profits take many forms and are essential for economic growth. Profitable companies find ways to hire, to contribute to their communities, and to pay taxes. When viewed in the context of the business cycle, profits act as a buffer to fluctuations in economic growth. As a buffer, profits fluctuate significantly over the cycle. Over time, however, profit growth tends to remain stable, indicating that the pace of profit growth corresponds with the pace of economic growth and the offsetting effects of changes in input costs and sales revenues. We also note that pricing margins and productivity tend to vary over the economic cycle. This provides a challenge to business leaders and financial investors in determining the profitability of an enterprise at any stage of the economic cycle.

In the first half of this chapter, we have provided an approach to separating trend from cycle so as to help decision makers in these areas. Volatility in corporate profits can be measured by calculating the mean, standard deviation, and stability ratio of data. All three measures should be calculated over several economic cycles to pin down the volatility of profits and provide perspective on equity market volatility and a sense of risk for equity investors. Profit data is also available for different sectors. Calculating measures of volatility will also provide perspective to investors and business leaders to better characterize the behavior of each sector. Later in this chapter, we will focus on modeling economic profits over the business cycle and the drivers in that model.

Profits: Behavior over the Economic Cycle

As a residual between two moving objects—revenues and costs—corporate profits can be quite volatile in the short run. Yet corporate profits are one of the clearest examples of the principles of dynamic adjustment and the role of information over the economic cycle.

On the revenue side, both output growth and output price fluctuations contribute to the change in revenues. Revenues will rise in response to an increase in economic output driven by higher aggregate demand in the economy. However, aggregate demand in the economy fluctuates over the business cycle. In the early phase of the economic recovery, a more rapid increase in demand will lead to an increase in output and thereby revenues. Prices are slower to respond to an increase in aggregate demand, making them lagging indicators of the economy. These observations reflect the dynamic and partial adjustment process in the economy. As a result, the actual day-to-day operations of output markets are not consistent with a frictionless, perfectly competitive view—particularly manufacturing. Therefore, our modeling of the profits process should reflect that imperfection.

Meanwhile, on the cost side, the short-run supply curve of any product is upward sloping owing to some factors of production (land, business structures) being fixed in the short run while other factors (labor) are variable, but subject to diminishing returns. That is, an increase in the application of the marginal factor, labor, applied to the other factors of production (land, business structures) generates a diminishing return in terms of output per unit of labor and a positive second derivative to the short-run supply curve.

numbered Display Equation

The Internal Dynamics of Prices, Labor Costs, and Profit Margins

Dynamic partial adjustment under conditions of imperfect information is also a characteristic of profit margins. As we have witnessed with the current cycle, firms tend to be extremely cautious to hire workers early in the economic recovery, and, as a result, employment gains have been modest. Yet labor costs are often the largest component of the marginal costs of any adjustment by a firm while increasing production. As a result, output increases are accompanied by modest price increases but even more modest marginal cost increases. Therefore, the spread between price and marginal cost widens in the early phase of an economic recovery. As the cycle progresses, unit labor costs tend to rise faster as labor productivity slows and compensation rises. The rise in unit labor costs tends to outpace the rise in output prices and thereby profit margins shrink (Figure 6.7). Interestingly, the consumer price index (CPI) outpaces unit labor costs in the early phase of recoveries (1982–1985, 1992–1997, 2001–2004, and 2010–2011) but then lags in the latter phase of the expansion.

Consumer price index versus unit labor costs graph shows curves for consumer price index in first quarter and unit labor costs in fourth quarter, during the period 1982 to 2015.

Figure 6.7 CPI vs. Unit Labor Costs

Source: U.S. Department of Labor

Increases in demand in the short run are not fully met by an increase in output as upward price movements along a supply curve come into play. In the short run, the output supply curve is upward sloping. Meanwhile, while short-run marginal costs do increase with increases in output, the price of outputs will rise relative to input prices.

In contrast to the perfectly competitive economic model, input prices do not respond quickly to variations in demand—labor compensation flexibility is limited. As we have witnessed in the current recovery, employment is not perfectly flexible. We are in an economic world characterized by frictions rather than perfect competition. Firms require specific skills, preventing perfect labor mobility, so firms prefer steady employment levels since decreases in employment engender trained workers to leave or have their skills depreciate. Moreover, varying employment is costly to firms’ reputations as workers prefer stable employment.

Productivity improves in the early phase of an economic recovery while compensation picks up in the latter phase of an economic expansion (Figure 6.8). Although productivity gains are certainly tied to real wages over a longer time frame, within a business cycle the slack in the labor market is a more important driver of wages. As a result, the marginal costs for labor are extremely pro-cyclical. Therefore, profit margins decline as the economic expansion continues. Imperfections in the labor and goods markets play a central role in the cyclical pattern of corporate profits.

Graph shows curves for nonfarm productivity and nonfarm unit labor cost in fourth quarter, during the period 2000 to 2016. Nonfarm unit labor cost with steep decline between 2010 and 2011.

Figure 6.8 Productivity, Compensation Unit Labor Costs: Nonfarm

Source: U.S. Department of Labor

Corporate Profits and the Midpoint of the Business Cycle

One of the most basic metrics for business decision makers is corporate profitability. With such an emphasis placed on this one metric, it is important to understand how profits evolve over the business cycle in order to anticipate the future needs of the business. For example, as we reach further into the current business cycle, it is time to contemplate cost-cutting strategies in order to mitigate potential losses as profitability growth begins to slow. Conversely, if profitability growth is anticipated to increase, it would be in a firm’s best interest to take advantage of expansion opportunities sooner in order to build or maintain a competitive advantage over time. In addition to the importance of understanding the economic operating environment, we find that, through analyzing corporate profits and their economic determinates, we can apply these metrics to more precisely identify the midpoints of business cycles. In addition, we explore one of the most commonly employed metrics to gauge business optimism, the debt-to-equity (D-E) ratio, which we find may not be the most applicable metric in determining fluctuations in corporate profits or business cycles.

Key Macroeconomic Drivers of Corporate Profit Growth

We began our analysis by decomposing the corporate profits cycle and describe its relationship to the business cycle to help decision makers determine where they are in the business cycle. We now turn to some key macroeconomic variables that economists focus on throughout the business cycle to help anticipate future trends in corporate profits during economic contractions and economic expansions. Finally, we analyze the aggregate corporate profits and their links to several business optimism metrics to also help determine how firms are responding to expectations about the future path of economic growth.

Productivity and Unit Labor Costs

Now that we have a sense of how corporate profits evolve throughout the business cycle, we turn to metrics that can provide some framework for determining future growth in corporate profits. There are two key metrics that economists exploit as inputs to determine the trend behind corporate profit cycles: labor productivity and unit labor costs. Although capital is also an important component of the business input-output equation, in a large, service-driven economy like the United States, labor productivity and unit labor costs explain most of the variance in corporate profits since 1947.9

Labor productivity is a measure of output per hour worked. Unit labor costs refer to the rise in labor compensation per hour relative to the labor’s real output per hour. Monitoring the trends behind these two metrics can provide some predictive power in understanding future trends in corporate profits (Figure 6.9 and Figure 6.10). Productivity tends to decline rapidly as output slows heading into a recession (2006–2007). More telling is the trend in unit labor costs, which tends to accelerate before an economic downturn as the labor market tightens and wages rise (1990, 2000, and 2006). Thus, the higher labor costs in light of falling output places downward pressure on corporate profits. Conversely, during the early recovery phase of an economic expansion, growth in output and profitability outpaces labor compensation and unit labor cost decline. The net result is higher corporate profit growth (1992–1994, 2002, and 2010).

Graph shows curves for output per hour in fourth quarter and corporate profit in third quarter, during the period 1990 to 2016. Corporate profits with steep decline between 2008 and 2010.

Figure 6.9 Nonfarm Productivity vs. Corporate Profits

Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce and U.S. Department of Labor

Unit labor costs versus corporate profits graph shows unit labor costs in fourth quarter and corporate profits in third quarter, during the period 1990 to 2016.

Figure 6.10 Unit Labor Costs vs. Corporate Profits

Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce and U.S. Department of Labor

The relationship between corporate profits and productivity and unit labor costs can be utilized to define turning points in the business cycle. As can be borne out during the past three expansions, the point at which productivity growth begins to exceed corporate profit growth has typically signaled the midpoint of a business cycle (1985–1986, 1996–1997) and a danger signal toward the end of the cycle (1989, 2000, 2007). Looking at unit labor costs compared to corporate profits, the midpoint of business cycles since the 1980s has been marked by unit labor costs growing more rapidly while at the same time corporate profits begin to contract (1985–1986, 1998, 2006–2007).

Saving vs. Spending Decisions

Profits are the major source of corporate cash flow and dividend payments, which serve as a return to savers and investors over time. Corporate cash flow roughly equals profits less dividend payments and inventory adjustment (often negative) plus deductions for capital consumption allowances (depreciation). Profits and retained earnings are the driving sources for dividend payments that, in turn, provide the returns to savers and investors via their 401(k)s, pensions, and individual retirement accounts (IRAs). As illustrated in Figure 6.11, there is a clear, positive link between profits and dividends. Two points are worth mentioning. Profits tend to lead dividends, as illustrated in the periods 1988–1991, 1994–2000, 2002–2007, and, most recently, from 2009 to 2012. This leading relationship exists on both the up- and downside of the economic cycle. This link establishes the importance of profits to the returns on financial investments and is a key to middle-income households in achieving a certain standard of living in retirement. Dividends, in turn, are a major, and increasingly sizeable, component of personal income, as illustrated in Figure 6.12, as pensions and other investment vehicles become more widely held among all households.

After-tax corporate profits versus dividend income graph shows curves for corporate profits after tax and dividend income in second quarter during the period 1982 to 2015. Dividend income with steep decline between 2009 and 2012.

Figure 6.11 After-Tax Corporate Profits vs. Dividend Income

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

Graph shows curve for dividends as a share of personal income in third quarter, during the period 1982 to 2015 with steep decline between 2009 and 2010.

Figure 6.12 Dividends as a Share of Personal Income

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

Profits and Risk

In economics, profits are a signal of financial success and credit quality. As a result, there is a sense that profits are negatively related to risk. As profits improve, there is less risk associated with the provision of credit in any given economic activity. For equity investors, an increase in profits is associated over time with a rise in dividends and, thereby, a reduction in the cost of equity finance. This tends to make profits and equity issuance pro-cyclical. For example, profits have a tendency to lead gains in equity prices, benchmarked here by the Standard & Poor’s (S&P) 500 index (Figure 6.13). In turn, gains in initial public offering (IPO) issuance and merger-and-acquisition activity tend to follow the S&P 500 (Figure 6.14). The cost of equity finance reflects the anticipated dividend yield plus expected nominal growth of dividends. Gains in profit growth provide the basis for dividend growth and lower the cost of equity finance.

After-tax corporate profits versus S&P 500 index shows curves for corporate profits after tax in second quarter and S&P 500 index in third quarter, during the period 1982 to 2015.

Figure 6.13 After-Tax Corporate Profits vs. S&P 500 Index

Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce and S&P

Bar diagram shows U.S. merger-and-acquisition volume in fourth quarter, during the period 2010 to 2016. It also shows curve for S&P 500 index in third quarter.

Figure 6.14 U.S. Merger-and-Acquisition Volume and S&P 500 Index

Sources: Bloomberg LP and S&P

Profit growth also tends to lead credit finance activity. Profit growth is again a signaling device for greater opportunity and a reduction in the credit risk associated with bank lending. Gains in profit growth in 1993–1994, 2002–2004, and again in 2012 are associated with growth in bank loans (Figure 6.15). On the bond side, improvement in profit growth tends to be associated with declines in credit spreads (Figure 6.16). Strong profit growth in 1988, 1994–1996, 2004–2006, and 2009–2011 is associated with a decline in the Baa over the 10-year Treasury spread. As a result, profits provide a signal about the viability of repayment from the lender’s point of view. Improvement in profit growth signals an improving view of credit quality and likelihood of repayment down the road by borrowers to lenders.

Graph shows two curves for corporation profits after tax in second quarter and U.S. bank loans in third quarter, during the period 1982 to 2015.

Figure 6.15 After-Tax Corp. Profits vs. Bank Loans

Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce and Federal Reserve Board

Graph shows curves for corporate profits after tax in second quarter and Baa - 10 year treasury spread in third quarter, during the period 1982 to 2015.

Figure 6.16 After-Tax Corporate Profits vs. Baa Corporate Bond Spread

Sources: U.S. Department of Commerce and Federal Reserve Board

Profits as Return for Innovation, Entrepreneurship: Signals of Success, Opportunity

Profit growth alters the nonfinancial corporate ratio of capital spending minus internally generated funds (Figure 6.17). The rise in profits leads to gains in internally generated funds that, in turn, can provide greater financial support for investment and encouragement to entrepreneurial spirits—as proxied by improving profit expectations and equity valuations (Figure 6.18).

Graph shows curve for financing gap in third quarter during the period 1982 to 2014 with highest peak between 2000 and 2002 and steep decline at 2010.

Figure 6.17 Financing Gap

Source: Federal Reserve Board

Graph shows two curves for corporate profits after tax and research and development in second quarter, during the period 1982 to 2015.

Figure 6.18 After-Tax Corporate Profits vs. Research & Development

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

Finally, profit growth tends to be associated with gains in business investment in plants and equipment (Figure 6.19). Profit growth that is directed to capital spending will tend to maintain the capital-output ratio and, along with that, the hiring of workers. Moreover, the investment undertaken would be anticipated to increase corporate share values and thereby feed back into earnings and dividends and the improvement of household incomes over time.

Graph shows curves for corporate profits after tax and business fixed investment in second quarter during the period 1982 to 2015.

Figure 6.19 After-Tax Corporate Profits vs. Business Fixed Investment

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

One Final Note: Cyclical Profits and Stationary Benchmarks

Many investment decisions reflect a judgment on profits as a return on equity, and yet we see that this measure of investment performance has a distinct cyclical character. Given this cyclical character, establishing an absolute level of value attached to any return on equity is likely to be a misleading guide to investing, since both profit growth and profits as a percentage of GDP vary significantly over the economic cycle. Establishing a single value for the return on equity would run counter to the cyclical character of the series. Therefore, an investor would view values above average as too expensive when, in fact, those values would reflect an improving economy. In turn, a slower pace of profit growth, especially when equity valuations look attractive, may reflect a weakening economy and might represent a challenge to current market valuations.

Moreover, the cyclical behavior of profit growth will also vary between economic sectors over the business cycle. Two sectors of the economy could exhibit different returns on equity patterns over the same economic cycle. At the sector level, some economic sectors, such as manufacturing, may be more sensitive to the economic cycle than other sectors, such as health care. This reinforces the view that any absolute benchmark for value in investing might be misleading when dealing with a cyclical series such as the return on equity, that itself varies by the sector under study. There is not a uniform standard for all sectors or for a uniform standard for the stage of the economic cycle.

Modeling the Profit Process

We model the pattern of profit growth as a function of the behavior of revenues and costs over the business cycle. On the revenue side, we examine the patterns of economic growth and prices. On the cost side, we examine unit labor costs, the unemployment rate, and interest rates as a proxy for capital (nonlabor) costs.

Some Fundamental Rules of Building a Forecasting Model

We present a model-based forecasting approach to generate reliable forecasts of an economic/financial variable, such as corporate profits.10 Here are some fundamental rules. First, a preferred model should perform better (produces a smaller forecast error, on average) than a benchmark or competing models in a simulated out-of-sample forecasting experiment. Second, it is necessary to establish a benchmark forecasting approach for comparison, so we adopt an autoregressive of order one, AR(1), method as a standard benchmark. All competing models should perform better than the AR(1) model’s forecasts.

Third, different forecasting approaches should be employed in a modeling process. That is, one possible approach would be a pure statistical method, which does not include any additional variables. One such technique is called an Autoregressive Integrated Moving Averages (ARIMA) model. In the forecasting process, it is always preferable to include as much information (in terms of predictors) as possible, along with a better econometric method to lead to a better forecast. In the Bayesian Vector Autoregressions (BVAR) modeling procedure, we can incorporate more information than a traditional econometric framework. The AR, ARIMA, and BVAR techniques are explained in great detail in Silvia et al. (2014).

The final rule to building a reliable forecasting model is that the model selection criterion should correspond with the forecast objective. For instance, our objective is to forecast the near-term (up to one year ahead) outlook of corporate profits. That implies we are interested in a four-quarter-ahead out-of-sample forecast of corporate profits growth. Therefore, we set a four-quarter-ahead simulated out-of-sample root mean square error (RMSE) as the forecast evaluation criterion for the competing models. The model that produces the smallest four-quarter-out RMSE (i.e., smallest average forecast error) would be the preferred model.

A Recursive Method of Model Selection

To calculate the out-of-sample RMSE, we assume that data is available between t = 1 and t = T for modeling purposes, where T represents the most recent data point—in this case, 2014:Q2. In addition, we are interested in h-step-ahead forecasts, where h = 1, 2, 3, 4, up to four quarters ahead. Assume an integer variable q that varies from 1 to q using one quarter as a unit. For each q, we choose data between t = 1 and t = Tq to build a model and apply it to generate h-step-ahead forecasts. We then calculate the out-of-sample RMSE for each step (from one quarter ahead to four quarters ahead). The magnitude of the RMSE statistic is utilized to compare the out-of-sample performance of each model, and the model with the smallest RMSE is the best model among its competitors.

We estimate all three models using data from the sample period 1982:Q1—2002:Q4 and generate four-quarter-out forecasts. Then, we move one quarter ahead, using data from 1982:Q1 to 2003:Q1, and again produce forecasts for the next four quarters. We employ this recursive method until we reach the final data point that is 1982:Q1–2013:Q2. We then calculate the out-of-sample RMSE for each quarter. In total, we have 42 forecast errors for each quarter ahead forecast. Table 6.3 shows the out-of-sample RMSE for each quarter ahead, up to four quarters, as well as the average RMSE for corporate profit growth rates.

Table 6.3 Simulated Out-of-Sample RMSE for Corporate Profits

Model Forecast Horizon, Quarters Ahead
1 2 3 4 Average
AR 6.21 10.66 12.77 12.85 10.62
ARIMA 5.78 8.96 11.07 12.41 9.55
BVAR 4.59 5.06 5.89 7.44 5.74

The one-quarter-ahead RMSE for the BVAR model is 4.59 and four-quarter RMSE is 7.44. On average, as well as for each quarter, the BVAR model produces the smallest RMSE compared to the benchmark AR(1) model and the competing ARIMA model. Therefore, the BVAR model is our preferred model to generate forecasts for corporate profits.

As suspected, the RMSE values increase with the forecast horizon for all three models, which indicates forecast uncertainty increases with the forecast horizon. A model selection criterion should be consistent with the forecast objective, since values of the four-quarter-out RMSE are much larger than those of one-quarter-out RMSE. In fact, for the AR and ARIMA models, four-quarter RMSE values are more than twice the values of one-quarter-ahead RMSE. That corresponds with the notion that further-out forecasting contains higher uncertainty. In addition, the out-of-sample RMSE is a practical statistic to build a forecast band (upper and lower limit). If we build a forecast band based on the one-quarter-out RMSE value, then that band will be narrower (and, ideally, more precise) than the one based on the four-quarter-ahead RMSE.

Table 6.4 shows the out-of-sample RMSE for the ratio of nonfinancial corporate profits to output of nonfinancial corporate business (NFC ratio). The BVAR model produces the smallest RMSE for each quarter as well as the average RMSE.

Table 6.4 Simulated Out-of-Sample RMSE for NFC Ratio

Model Forecast Horizon, Quarters Ahead
1 2 3 4 Average
AR 0.008 0.014 0.016 0.021 0.014
ARIMA 0.007 0.012 0.015 0.020 0.013
BVAR 0.005 0.009 0.011 0.012 0.009

The forecasting performance of the BVAR approach is the best among all three models as it produces the smallest out-of-sample RMSE, on average, or the smallest average forecast error. Therefore, we employ the BVAR approach to forecast corporate profits growth rates (Figure 6.20) and the NFC ratio (Figure 6.21). In addition, in Figures 6.20 and 6.21, we plot the out-of-sample forecast with actual data and in-sample fitted values from all three approaches for corporate profits and NFC ratio.

Graph shows four curves depicting the corporate profit growth forecasts for actual, AR, ARIMA and BVAR, during the period 2008 to 2016. Actual with highest peak between 2009 and 2010 and decline at 2011.

Figure 6.20 Corporate Profits Growth Forecasts

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

Graph shows four curves depicting NFC ratio for forecasts actual, AR, ARIMA and BVAR, during the period 2008 to 2016. Four curves shows steep decline between 2009 and 2010.

Figure 6.21 NFC Ratio Forecasts

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

One observation from the out-of-sample forecast from these three models is that the AR and ARIMA models produce similar forecasts and connote a continuously upward trend in corporate profits. That is one potential issue with both AR and ARIMA approaches, especially during multiperiod-out forecasting. Typically, and in the present case, both AR and ARIMA models linearly extend the series for the out-of-sample period. However, many economic and financial series experience nonlinear growth rates. For instance, profit growth rates are volatile over time, that is, profit growth was 4.7 percent for 2013:Q4 and –4.8 percent for 2014:Q1. The BVAR model, however, shows a bounceback for 2014:Q4 and then slower growth for the next couple of quarters, which is more realistic than the linear upward trend indicated by the AR and ARIMA models. The same observation can be observed in the case of the NFC ratio as the AR/ARIMA models both produce a linear downward trend.

CONCLUDING REMARKS: MODELING PROFITS

Profits exhibit a complex set of behaviors over the business cycle since there are a number of influences on both the cost and revenue side of the equation. The common approach to modeling profits fails to deal with this variable, cyclical character. When we apply the BVAR technique on profit growth and profits as a share of nonfinancial corporate output, our results are superior to standard linear models and allow us an added advantage, which can prove serviceable to investors and decision makers.

NOTES

..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset