Chapter 3
Economic Foundations

3.1 Macroeconomics and Microeconomics

In economics, a distinction is made between microeconomics and macroeconomics. Whereas macroeconomics deals with aggregate economic quantities such as national output, unemployment, and inflation issues, microeconomics concerns the behavior of individual economic units, such as consumers, workers, and individual organizations. More explicitly, the field of microeconomics studies and explains the decision-making of these individual economic units from an economic and rational viewpoint. Hence, when investigating operational safety decision-making in an organizational context, microeconomics is the research field of primary interest.

Microeconomics may help us to understand, for example, safety indifference curves, safety utilities, safety investments, safety budgeting, equilibrium safety levels, and the like. It should be mentioned that microeconomics deals with both positive and normative questions. When discussing safety investment decisions, in particular, it is important to differentiate between the two approaches. Positive economics refers to the objective scientific descriptions, explanations, and predictions based on certain facts and to the explanation of how an organization takes decisions. It involves the development of economic theories, models, and facts and it can be regarded as the “science” aspect of economics, which aims to explain, optimize, and predict decisions of individual economic units. It will not, however, consider aspects such as how an individual firm distributes its bonuses among its managers, or how safety benefits should be spent among the workers. Conversely, normative economics refers to the policy decisions and views that individual economic units have about a particular issue, and therefore relates to subjective judgments or preferences [1]. There are no “right” or “wrong” answers in relation to normative economic decisions, as they are determined solely by an individual's (or a group of individuals') views.

It is important, therefore, when discussing operational safety economics and the financial implications of decisions, to distinguish between the views expressed by a safety economist who is presenting information based on evidence and those of a safety economist who is merely presenting a personal opinion. This book is mainly concerned with the position of operational safety in microeconomics from a “positive” viewpoint, and with how principles, concepts, and theories used in microeconomics may be applied to safety, in an objective way. Nevertheless, this book also discusses some normative perspectives, because operational safety within single organizations always also involves normative parameters in the decision-making process. In fact, Chapter 7 elaborates further on normative decision-making with respect to operational economics, as a beyond-the-state-of-the-art approach.

3.2 Safety Demand and Long-term Average Cost of Production

3.2.1 Safety Demand

An essential concept in economic theory is that of “demand.” Demand is the quantity of goods and services that consumers may want to purchase at a specific price. Due to the usefulness of a certain good or service, some people are interested in purchasing it; it has a value for these consumers, and thus a certain price follows. The demand will then change depending on the price. In the case of operational safety economics, one might reason that the good or service represents safety or, more specific, safety measures: the demand curve of a safety good or service (e.g., a safety measure or a portfolio of safety measures) depends on the price of the safety good or service. Even if all goods and services (in this case, operational safety) were free to the consumer, there would be a limit on how much consumers could use. Therefore, there would be a demand figure even at this price. In case of safety, this restriction would, for example, be imposed by production and physical limitations of implementing the safety measures. The reason is simple: every production, no matter how small, goes hand in hand with risks, even if operational safety were free of costs.

In general, in economics, the demand curve defines the purchase characteristics of consumers at all conceivable prices, whereas the quantity demanded defines the purchase characteristics of consumers at a particular price. Demand depends on a number of parameters. In case of safety as a good or service, it first depends on the preferences of safety managers and their safety utility curves (see Section 3.5.1). Second, it depends on the available safety budget of an organization. In general, the higher the budget, the higher the demand. Third, it depends on the number of organizations needing this specific kind of safety good or service. The more companies that need it, the higher the demand. Fourth, the demand will be influenced by the industrial sector where the safety good or service is used. The demand of safety can differ drastically from sector to sector, due to the industrial activities and agreements with unions, legislation, profit, and income specificities within the sectors. Fifth, in case of some safety goods or services, a substitution effect may be observed, for example, if the price rises. In this case, the price relative to the prices of other safety goods or services is important, not the absolute price of the good or service.

To investigate the influence of each of the parameters on the safety demand, every parameter can be changed or fluctuated while the other factors are kept constant (according to the well-known “ceteris paribus” – other things being equal – principle).

Thus far, safety was looked upon from the perspective of “safety measures,” and the price of safety measures influenced by the possible market demand. This reasoning assumes that safety is a regular good comparable with all other goods and/or services. However, this is not the case and a regular demand curve for safety such as for other goods and services is not applicable. Some safety measures, almost no matter how expensive, will be purchased anyway, and others might only be purchased for the happy few who have a company culture strongly tending toward high reliability organization (HRO) safety and who are also able to afford them. In other words, the purchase of safety measures within an organization strongly depends on a lot of other factors besides the market mechanism. The classic microeconomic demand function therefore does not fully apply to safety.

Safety is thus not a regular good or service, such as a book or a football match . Safety is actually, as already mentioned in this book, a “dynamic non-event.” As such, in economic terms, companies purchase a certain level of non-events over a certain period of time. The higher the price of non-events, the harder it is to obtain a lot of them and the lower the number of non-events that are purchased. In other words, if safety per unit costs more, there will be less safety demand per unit. This is illustrated in Figure 3.1. Notice that this figure only holds for one type of risk at a time. Hence, the figure should be seen in terms of either type I risks and avoiding type I accident scenarios, or type II risks and avoiding type II accident scenarios.

nfgz001

Figure 3.1 An illustrative safety demand curve.

In standard works on microeconomy, the next step is to elaborate and show a supply curve, in order to finally explain the equilibrium mechanism and the market equilibrium, based on demand and supply curves. In the case of safety, however, it makes no sense to develop a supply curve. As “supply” can be defined as the quantity of goods and services that producers may want to sell at a specified price, in safety terms this would mean the number of non-events that a company would want to sell at a certain price. Of course, the company does not want to sell safety, or non-events, it just needs a certain level of safety itself. Therefore, although a demand curve of safety exists within a single company and on a microeconomic level, it is useless in this context to talk about a supply curve.

Safety goods and services can also be viewed from the perspective of the profitability of a company, and thus in that regard be linked to micro-economic theory.

3.2.2 Long-term Average Cost of Production and Safety

Looking at how safety influences the profitability of a company can be done via the so-called long-term average cost of production (LAC). Before explaining more microeconomic theories and models in depth, it is interesting to consider why safety economics and investing in safety – or not – may indeed make the difference to an organization in terms of its long-term profitability. The profitability of any organization depends on its profitability in the long term, and this in turn depends on the LAC of the firm. The average cost of production can be defined as the total cost of production divided by the total output in goods and services. In other words, the average cost of production can be seen as a proxy for the accumulated operational negative uncertainties divided by the accumulated operational positive uncertainties within an organization. Further, assume that the type of organization considered in this book is aimed at long-term existence and making profits in a sustainable way. In this case, to ensure the long-term viability of a company, the average cost of production should be less than the price at which the goods and services can be traded.

Inputs to production comprise any goods or services that are used to produce the output product or service, including, for example, labor costs, raw materials, utilities, and equipment, but also safety and safety-related goods and services (such as risk assessments, maintenance operations, and training). The production function determines the maximum output that can be produced from a defined level of inputs. The efficiency with which an organization achieves a specific output will define its long-term average costs. The importance of safety within the average costs of production can be illustrated by a simple example.

The costs, in broad terms, will vary with production output. As the production output increases, the unit costs of production will go down due to fixed costs staying the same irrespective of the production output (economies of scale). However, at a certain point, costs will rise again due to more levels of management, more difficult organizational management, transport costs, marketing costs, geographical location costs, and so on (diseconomies of scale). Hence, an organization's long-term average cost curve is likely to follow more or less the shape of the curve depicted in Figure 3.2.

nfgz002

Figure 3.2 Long-term average costs of production (LAC) for the illustrative example of companies A and B.

Figure 3.2 shows the LAC curves of companies A and B. Both companies can sell their goods or services in the market at €50 per unit. However, company A can sell at a profit if it sells quantities of the good or service between c03-math-0001 and c03-math-0002, whereas company B may be able to sustain production at a loss in the short term. Company B will have to lower its production costs if it desires to keep operating for a longer period of time though. Company B can, for example, lower its production costs by improving its health and safety standards and thereby suffering lower accident costs.

3.3 Safety Value Function

A safety value function is a real-value mathematical function defined over an evaluation criterion that represents an option's measure of “goodness” over the levels of the criterion. If we take “operational safety” as the criterion to be evaluated, a measure of goodness reflects a safety manager's judged value in the performance of an option across the levels of operational safety. In practice, the safety value function for operational safety's least preferred level (i.e., very low operational safety scores) takes the value 0. The safety value function of operational safety's most preferred level (i.e., very high operational safety scores) takes the value 1.

Notice that it is not always straightforward to assign a value to the criterion “operational safety.” As an example, the differences between the scores of type I risks (or occupational safety) and type II risks (or safety with respect to major accidents) may be important to assess and to take into account in the value function. Preference of one type over another type is quite personal (cf. risk-averse/risk-neutral/risk-seeking character) and may even change over time for an individual, depending on personal experiences and changing conditions or circumstances. There are, however, also many various preference levels even within type I or type II operational risks.

Ideally, a safety value function should be measurable, to be able to use it in practice. Hence, a preference ordering and a strength of preference between operational safety measures should be present. The safety value difference between any two measures with respect to operational safety represents a safety manager's strength of preference between the two measures. Hence, the vertical axis of a measurable safety value function is an ordinal scale measure of the strength of a safety manager's preferences. An ordinal value (on the vertical axis) is thus combined with a categorical value (on the horizontal axis). For the safety manager, the values on the vertical axis have meaningful preference differences, while the distances between A, B, C, D, and E along the horizontal axis are not meaningful (see Figure 3.3 for an example of a safety value function).

nfgz003

Figure 3.3 An illustrative safety value function.

As illustrated in Figure 3.3, the safety values not only display an ordering of preferences (ordinal scale), but also the strengths of preferences (interval scale). It is clear from the figure that there is a smaller increment in safety value between D and E than between A and B, for example. In fact, the safety value increment between A and B is approximately three times the safety value increment between D and E. The expression “safety value increment” indicates the degree to which the safety manager prefers one (higher) score over another (lower) score.

An approach to specifying a single dimensional safety value function is the direct subjective assessment of the safety value, or “direct rating.” To this end, all alternatives can be ranked by a safety manager or a safety management team on a line such that the ranking and the position of the alternative reflect a numerical assessment.

The rating scale approach to value safety has its fundamentals in psychometric theory. The method concerns a single line with anchor points that represent the best possible safety situation and the worst possible safety situation. For example (see also Figure 3.4), the worst safety measure/bundle corresponds to 20% probability of a type I accident per year (this anchor point serves as the left wall or floor), whereas the best safety measure/bundle might correspond to 1% probability of a type I accident per year (this anchor point then serves as the ceiling or right wall). Safety managers (or a safety management team) can then be asked to put several alternative type I safety measures/bundles on this line, in such a way that the points they mark on the line reflect the differences between the safety measures/bundles described. Evidently, this method generates values rather than utilities (see Section 3.5), as choices between different measures/bundles are not made pairwise, and it also does not involve decision-making under uncertainty.

nfgz004

Figure 3.4 A rating scale example.

Rating scales can thus be employed to measure the responses of a safety manager or a safety management team on a continuum or in an ordered set of categories, with numerical values assigned to each point or category.

3.4 Expected Value Theory, Value at Risk, and Safety Attitude

3.4.1 Expected Value Theory

The expected value associated with a situation where uncertainty is involved is a weighted average of the payoffs or values associated with all possible outcomes, with the probabilities of each outcome used as weights. Hence, the expected value measures the average payoff. To illustrate this, assume the following possible consequences of a certain undesired event, “c03-math-0003”:

  1. Outcome 1: a cost of c03-math-0004 with probability c03-math-0005
  2. Outcome 2: a cost of c03-math-0006 with probability c03-math-0007
  3. Outcome 3: a cost of c03-math-0008 with probability c03-math-0009.

Assume that no other outcomes are possible, i.e. that,

equation

Then, the expected value of the undesired event is:

equation

The decision to take preventive measures or not against this particular undesired event with three possible outcomes is in the hands of the safety manager.

The expected value also refers to the weighted average value of all costs or effectiveness outcomes in a decision analysis tree. In safety management, event trees are often used to visualize different outcomes and their consequences and/or probabilities. Such trees can thus also be used to carry out decision analyses by calculating expected values using the information in the tree. An illustrative example is provided in Figure 3.5.

nfgz005

Figure 3.5 An illustrative example of a decision analysis tree for calculating the expected value.

3.4.2 Value at Risk

A term much used in financial risk management is the so-called value at risk (VaR). The question that a VaR tries to answer is simple: “What is the most that can be lost on a particular financial investment with a certain level of confidence (typically 95% or 99%)?” VaR indeed provides a predicted loss over a target time horizon within a given confidence interval. The loss is usually called “maximum loss” (or “worst-case loss”) in financial risk management, but there is actually a chance that an even greater loss may occur, albeit small. In brief, a VaR measure determines an amount of money, such that there is that probability of the portfolio of assets not losing that amount of money over that time horizon. Hence, in statistical terms, this is called a percentile. So a 1-year 95% euro VaR is just the 95 percentile of a portfolio's yearly loss expressed in euros (see also Section 7.2.1.1).

This VaR can also be explained in terms of operational risk management. For example, if the worst-case summed consequence of accident scenarios (“VaR” in financial risk management terminology) in an organization is calculated to be €100 million/year, with a 95% confidence level, then there is only a 5% chance that the summed consequences of accident scenarios will be higher than €100 million over any given year.

In operational risk management, a VaR could be used for decision-making for type I, and also for type II, risks, as probability distributions can be used for both types of risk, and this kind of input information is needed for VaR statistic calculations. A VaR statistic indeed needs, among other things, an estimated input of loss (either in currency or in percentage terms) as a probability density.

A Monte Carlo simulation, randomly generating outcomes for a number of hypothetical trials, can be used to calculate the VaR.

The downside of using a VaR for operational risk management is that: (i) there is still a lot of epistemic uncertainty about type II risks (and thus the accuracy and probability distribution depend on the assumptions made and the scenarios considered); (ii) there is still a certain probability that a greater loss may occur; and (iii) due to (i) and (ii), avoiding a true disaster is not fully taken into account while using this VaR method for making safety investments.

3.4.3 Safety Attitude

One approach to characterizing a person's risk attitude is via the concept of the so-called “certainty equivalent.” A certainty equivalent is a value c03-math-0012, such that the safety manager is indifferent between the consequences of the undesired event and the value c03-math-0013 that he obtains for certain.

Hence, depending on the certainty equivalent, safety managers can be categorized as being safety-seeking, safety-neutral, or safety-averse:

  1. Safety-seeking: Certainty equivalent of investment > expected value of undesired event
  2. Safety-neutral: Certainty equivalent of investment = expected value of undesired event
  3. Safety-averse: Certainty equivalent of investment < expected value of undesired event.

Looking at it from the “hypothetical benefit” point of view, safety-seeking, safety-neutral, and safety-averse can be compared to risk-seeking, risk-neutral, and risk-averse. In case of “risk,” there is a possibility to win and to have a positive financial payoff, i.e., in this case, a hypothetical benefit of being safe. In the case of “safety,” the gains are equal to “not losing” or “not having accidents,” and hence they can be interpreted as necessary prevention investments to avoid human, social, and legal, losses. They thus represent the costs that go hand in hand with safety. Hence, in the case of safety there is no possibility of achieving a real positive financial payoff – the payoff is a hypothetical one. In this way, safety managers can be categorized into being risk-averse, risk-neutral, or risk-seeking:

  1. Risk averse: Certainty equivalent of positive outcome < expected value of positive outcome
  2. Risk neutral: Certainty equivalent of positive outcome = expected value of positive outcome
  3. Risk seeking: Certainty equivalent of positive outcome > expected value of positive outcome.

A risk-averse person, for instance, is willing to accept, with certainty, an amount of money (i.e., a positive outcome) less than the expected amount that might be received if a decision were made to participate in a gamble. Risk-neutral and risk-seeking behavior can be understood in a similar manner.

3.5 Safety Utilities

3.5.1 Safety Utility Functions

A safety utility can be seen as a measure of safety management's satisfaction from a certain level of operational safety within an organization. Safety utilities can thus be employed to explain the economic behavior of a company's management in terms of attempts to increase operational safety. The “utility” concept is usually applied in economics by using indifference curves (see Section 3.7), which in operational economics represent the combination of measures that a safety management team would accept to maintain a given level of satisfaction.

A class of mathematical functions exhibits behaviors with respect to risk-seeking, risk-neutral, and risk-averse attitudes. These can be regarded as “safety utility” (Su) functions. Figure 3.6 illustrates these functions.

nfgz006

Figure 3.6 Safety utility functions (risk-averse, risk-neutral, and risk-seeking).

A safety utility is a measure of preference that a certain safety situation or state has for a safety manager. Mathematically, it is a dimensionless number. A safety utility function is a real-value mathematical function comparable to the safety value function, the difference being that the safety value is, in this case, an abstract dimensionless “safety utility” related to a safety situation or state, and not, as in the safety value functions, a concrete safety value attached to a certain option of an operational safety measure or bundle. The approach to determine the functions is also different.

The vertical axis of a utility function can be any real number, but usually the axis is scaled between 0 and 100 or 0 and 1. If the latter range is chosen, the utility of the least preferred outcome is assigned “0” and the utility of the most preferred outcome is assigned “1.”

3.5.2 Expected Utility and Certainty Equivalent

The expected utility of an uncertain undesired event “c03-math-0022” with utilities c03-math-0023, c03-math-0024, …, c03-math-0025 of possible outcomes c03-math-0026, c03-math-0027, …, c03-math-0028, with respective probabilities c03-math-0029, c03-math-0030, …, c03-math-0031 is:

equation

Furthermore, it is possible to illustrate the relationship between the expected value c03-math-0033 of an undesired event and the expected utility c03-math-0034 of this undesired event. Figure 3.7 displays this relationship for a monotonically increasing risk-averse utility function.

nfgz007

Figure 3.7 Relationship between expected value and expected utility.

The equation of the chord from Figure 3.7 can be written as:

equation

We also know that c03-math-0036. If we set c03-math-0037 in the equation of the chord, then it can algebraically be shown that (see also Garvey [2]):

equation

Furthermore, the certainty equivalent (CE) is the value on the horizontal axis at which a person is indifferent between a lottery and receiving the amount CE with certainty. Hence, the utility of CE must be equal to the expected utility of a lottery; thus,

The information in Figure 3.7 shows this reasoning. From Eq. (3.1), it follows that when a safety utility function of a safety management team has been drafted and is known, the certainty equivalent CE can be determined by taking the inverse of the safety utility function:

equation

3.6 Measuring Safety Utility Functions

Utilities cannot be observed directly, and hence they have to be determined in another way. Economists therefore devised an approach to measure managers' relative utilities underlying their choice-making. Such an approach is also called the “revealed preference” in economics.

Measuring safety utilities involves a two-step procedure. The first step involves defining which safety states or situations are of interest. The second step involves trying to value those safety states or situations, and place them in a ranking order (first, second, third, etc.).

Straffin [3] indicates that to determine a safety manager's or a safety management team's safety utils on a cardinal (i.e., ratio or interval; see Section 2.11) scale, numbers need to be assigned to outcomes so that the ratios of differences between the numbers reflect something about the managers' or the team's preferences. As Von Neumann and Morgenstern [4] indicate, the relevant information can be obtained by asking questions about lotteries.

These ratio safety util numbers can be used to make further calculations (instead of interval or ordinal numbers where no mathematical manipulations are allowed), but it should be stressed that safety utils are defined only for one individual or one team, and refer to how that individual or that team makes choices among alternatives. Simply put, safety utils are just a convenient numerical way of organizing information from safety managers or a safety team about their preferences, given that those preferences satisfy certain consistency conditions.

It should be mentioned, however, that in general, the particular ratio util number is often not that important. For example, although it is impossible to say that safety managers on a higher utility value, c03-math-0082, are exactly twice as happy as they might be on a certain lower utility value, c03-math-0083, an interval or an ordinal util ranking is often sufficient to obtain an insight into how safety managers make individual decisions.

3.7 Preferences of Safety Management – Safety Indifference Curves

Given the large number of possible choices that have to be made by safety management regarding safety investments and safety measures, for example, between type I and type II risks, but also within the different types of risks, how can safety management preferences be described in a coherent way? The economic theory of consumer behavior provides the answer.

The theory of consumer behavior begins with basic assumptions regarding people's preferences for one choice (e.g., a safety bundle) versus another. The basic assumptions can be formulated with respect to safety management as follows:

  1. 1. Preferences are complete. Safety managers are thus able to compare and rank all safety bundles in order of their preference or utility value. For any two safety bundles c03-math-0084 and c03-math-0085, managers will prefer c03-math-0086 over c03-math-0087, or c03-math-0088 over c03-math-0089, or they will be indifferent between the two and will be equally happy with either bundle. Note that these preferences ignore costs. A safety manager might prefer a technology-based safety measure to a person-based measure but would buy the person-based measure because it is cheaper.
  2. 2. Preferences are transitive. Transitivity means that if a safety manager prefers safety bundle c03-math-0090 to safety bundle c03-math-0091, and prefers c03-math-0092 to c03-math-0093, then he also prefers c03-math-0094 to c03-math-0095. For example, if a manager prefers 6 technology measures + 10 organizational measures (bundle c03-math-0096) over 8 technology measures + 8 organizational measures (bundle c03-math-0097) and further prefers option c03-math-0098 to 10 technology measures + 6 organizational measures (bundle c03-math-0099), then the safety manager prefers c03-math-0100 to c03-math-0101. This transitivity assumption guarantees that the safety manager's preferences are consistent, and hence rational. Safety managers can, for example, use safety utility values to rank different bundles of safety goods and services.
  3. 3. All bundles are “desirable,” so that, leaving costs aside, safety managers always prefer more than fewer safety goods and services (bundles).
  4. 4. Safety indifference curves are convex, i.e., bowed inward. The term convex indicates that the slope of the safety indifference curve becomes less negative as one moves down along the curve. Safety managers have a marginal rate of substitution for one safety commodity compared with another safety commodity. Managers will therefore demonstrate a diminishing marginal rate of substitution, because decreasing quantities or qualities of one type of safety bundle are given up to obtain equal increases in the quantity or quality of the other safety bundle.

Safety management's preferences are described by safety indifference curves (also called iso-utility curves of safety in safety commodity space – see also the next paragraph), which identify those bundles of safety goods and services that provide the same utility to the individual safety manager or to the safety management team. A safety indifference curve thus represents all combinations of safety bundles that provide the same level of satisfaction to a safety manager or a team of safety managers. The actual shapes of the indifference curves will depend on the personal preferences of the manager or the team.

When indifference curves are discussed in microeconomic theory, the assumption is often made that the consumer has only two goods to choose from. Let c03-math-0102 be a variable which represents the number of safety goods “1” purchased by the safety management team, and let c03-math-0103 be a variable representing the safety management team's purchases of safety goods “2.” The couple c03-math-0104 represents a choice of a number for both safety goods and is called a “safety commodity bundle.” Assuming further that c03-math-0105 and c03-math-0106 should be non-negative numbers, then all possible safety commodity bundles can be represented geometrically in what can be called the “safety commodity space.” Safety managers have preferences about safety commodity bundles in safety commodity space: given any two safety commodity bundles, safety management either prefers one bundle over another or is indifferent between the two. If the safety management team's preferences satisfy the basic consistency assumptions from above, they are represented by so-called iso-utility functions in safety commodity space. A utility function assigns a real value to each safety commodity bundle. If safety management prefers commodity bundle c03-math-0107 to bundle c03-math-0108, then a higher number is assigned to c03-math-0109 than to c03-math-0110. The iso-utility function c03-math-0111 assigns the same number to all bundles on any given indifference curve. Figure 3.8 shows the indifference curves or iso-utility curves in the safety commodity space. The arrow in Figure 3.8 indicates the direction of preference. Safety commodity bundles on indifference curves far from the origin are preferred to those on indifference curves near the origin.

nfgz008

Figure 3.8 Indifference curves or iso-utility curves in a safety commodity space.

Indifference curves are often expressed, especially as a proxy, as functions of the Cobb-Douglas type. These functions are used because they represent nicely convex curves. The function then looks as follows:

equation

where c03-math-0113 is a parameter such that c03-math-0114.

Obviously, other indifference curve functions are possible and feasible as well.

3.8 Measuring Safety Indifference Curves

Determining safety indifference curves can be carried out by direct or indirect measurement. Direct measurement can be performed in a number of ways, one of which, the “time trade-off,” will be discussed further. Indirect measurement concerns using questionnaires that are given to safety managers or a safety management team. Questionnaires can be used for drafting indifference curves for type I risks, while time trade-off safety utilities can be used for drafting safety indifference curves for type II risks.

3.8.1 Questionnaire-based Type I Safety Indifference Curves

Investigating the preferences of an individual safety decision-maker or of a safety management team is possible through the development and use of questionnaires. Using human preferences derived from a well-constructed survey, an indifference curve can be drafted. In an organizational context, it is assumed that the individual decision-maker or the team represents the organization and makes decisions in its interest, and not in their own interest.

With respect to safety management, “revealed preference with discrete choice” (mentioned earlier in this book) is a very interesting and straightforward method (used within consumption theory) to obtain preferences. It is an approach to determine which bundle of goods and/or services is preferred over another bundle of goods and/or services. The method can be explained as follows. When a person (e.g., a safety manager) chooses a bundle A from a series of affordable alternatives, he thus reveals his preference for this bundle A over a series of other bundles he could have chosen. All other bundles within his budget that this person did not choose, represent a lower utility for him. Hence, if it were possible to determine all bundles having a higher utility and a lower utility than bundle A, it would also be possible to pinpoint all bundles having the same utility as bundle A (i.e., those bundles that were left over at the end of the exercise). Graphically, these leftover bundles together form the so-called indifference curve [5].

The purpose of the questionnaire is to determine such indifference curves. This can be achieved by letting a safety manager or a safety management team choose between two safety commodity bundles. If it is indicated that bundle 1 is preferred over bundle 2, the utility of bundle 2 will be increased, or the utility of bundle 1 will be decreased, until the situation occurs that the manager or management team displays an indifference between both safety commodity bundles. By repeating this procedure, it is possible to also determine other safety commodity bundles showing an equal utility. The more this procedure is repeated, the more accurate the resulting indifference curve will be.

In the following paragraphs, a concrete working procedure is described to reveal the preferences of safety management with respect to safety measure X in contrast to all other possible safety measures. It may be interesting to position the most important safety measure, according to the opinion of company safety management, in relation to all other safety measures, and in this way to determine the allocation of the safety budget.

The initial questions serve to obtain the required background information:

  1. 1. What is the company's safety budget?
  2. 2. What are all possible safety measures and what are their investment costs?
  3. 3. What is, according to you, the most important safety measure for the company?

The most important measure is then displayed in a graph versus the aggregate of all other possible measures. To determine the indifference curve, the respondent needs to make a number of choices using a number of closed questions, whereby every choice is between two safety commodity bundles.

A possible closed question can be:

  1. Bundle 1 contains four measures of type X and five other measures.
  2. Bundle 2 contains two measures of type X and seven other measures.

Make your choice:

  1. Bundle 1 is preferred over bundle 2.
  2. Bundle 2 is preferred over bundle 1.
  3. Indifference between bundle 1 and bundle 2.

It is then possible to develop an indifference curve in safety commodity space in the following manner. Figure 3.9 displays the initial choice between the two safety commodity bundles.

nfgz009

Figure 3.9 Choice between two safety commodity bundles.

If safety commodity bundle 1 is chosen over safety commodity bundle 2, bundle 1 obviously represents a higher utility for the respondent than bundle 2. The next step is to lower the utility of bundle 1 by decreasing the number of measures of type X by one unit. Hence, bundle c03-math-0115, positioned perpendicular beneath bundle 1, is used to formulate the following closed question:

  1. Bundle c03-math-0116 contains three measures of type X and five other measures.
  2. Bundle 2 contains two measures of type X and seven other measures.

Make your choice:

  1. Bundle c03-math-0117 is preferred over bundle 2.
  2. Bundle 2 is preferred over bundle c03-math-0118.
  3. Indifference between bundle c03-math-0119 and bundle 2.

In an analogous way, the utility of commodity bundle 1 can also be decreased by lowering the number of other measures, and hence by choosing a commodity bundle c03-math-0120 situated to the left of bundle 1 (see Figure 3.10a). This procedure is repeated until the respondent is indifferent between the two bundles. At that point, the two bundles have an equal utility and they then belong to the same indifference curve. Another analogous procedure is to increase the utility of bundle 2, and in this way determine the indifference curve (see Figure 3.10b).

nfgz010

Figure 3.10 Determining the points belonging to an indifference curve versus measure X: (a) method 1; (b) method 2.

The procedure described allows us to identify two points belonging to one indifference curve. To further determine other points belonging to this curve, bundles need to be compared two-by-two with a bundle belonging to the curve. Theoretically, this procedure needs to be repeated infinitely. Evidently, applying a procedure infinitely is impossible, and therefore in practice a limited number of points will be satisfactory to establish a proxy for the indifference curve of an individual safety decision-maker or a safety management team.

3.8.2 Problems with Determining an Indifference Curve

In trying to determine the preferences of safety management by using the procedure described in the previous section and the closed questions, a number of problems may be encountered that can influence the quality of the result. The main problem stems from the fact that humans do not always take decisions rationally, i.e., in a way that maximizes their utility. Often, decisions depend on rather arbitrary parameters, such as mood, temper, or the weather, leading to not following the condition of transitivity of preferences. One possible approach to deal with such variations is to add an extra term to take stochastic influences into consideration. However, introducing such a term would probably make the procedure too complex to be usable by most companies.

3.8.3 Time Trade-off-based Safety Utilities for Type II Safety Indifference Curves

As type II risks are characterized with much lower probabilities and much more severe outcomes, the method described in Section 3.8.1 would not be suitable for determining an indifference curve for such risks. It may be possible, however, to use the time trade-off approach in this case.

The time trade-off method asks people to consider relative amounts of time (such as the number of years a certain safety situation exists) that they would be willing to give up in order to achieve another safety situation. Consider the following two alternatives of one investment where a safety team may choose from:

  1. Safety situation A (e.g., 7% probability of an accident) during time period c03-math-0121;
  2. Safety situation B (e.g., 0.1% probability of an accident) during time period c03-math-0122.

Then, time period c03-math-0123 is varied until the safety team is indifferent between alternative A and alternative B. In this case, a point c03-math-0124 belonging to the indifference curve is obtained: c03-math-0125.

The following illustrative table may, for example, be obtained.

Quality-adjusted accident probabilities can be used to make decisions concerning prevention investments for type II risks more objective. As an illustrative example, from Table 3.1, if an installation I decreases in accident probability, for example, from 10% to 5%, and hence there is an increase in QAAP from 0.2 to 0.35, over 2000 years, and also (via other safety investments) from 10% to 7%, hence from 0.2 to 0.25, in the next 2000 years, then the total equivalent safety benefit for installation I is

Table 3.1 Quality-adjusted accident probabilities (QAAPs) for 0.1% probability over 2000 years

Accident probability (%) QAAP
70 0.05
50 0.1
20 0.12
10 0.20
7 0.25
5 0.35
1 0.4
0.5 0.5
equation

If installations c03-math-0127 and c03-math-0128, by a similar approach of calculations, received 0.35 and 0.40 QAAPs respectively, the total safety benefit would be c03-math-0129. Notice that this safety investment would be similar to (for example) the choice for a prevention investment leading to 0.95 QAAPs only for installation c03-math-0130, and no safety changes/improvements/investments for installations c03-math-0131 and c03-math-0132. In summary, this number (i.e., 0.95 QAAPs) represents a numerical estimate of a company's valuation of the safety investments for installations c03-math-0133, c03-math-0134, and c03-math-0135, and this can be compared with other possible safety investments within the company. This approach can be employed for very low probability risks.

Using QAAPs, different safety investments leading to changing accident probabilities at an industrial site can be compared with one another. Any investment leading to a decrease in accident probability leads to an increase in safety utility (expressed in QAAPs). This utility measure can then be used for comparing various safety investments.

A QAAP can thus be interpreted as a utility number expressing the value that a safety team assigns to a specific time period in a particular safety (accident probability) situation relative to the value of a reference safety situation (e.g., the 0.1% accident probability situation in the example above).

In short, time trade-off is a technique for generating a safety management team's or a safety manager's preferences by offering a hypothetical decision between a shorter time period of a higher safety situation (lower accident probability), on the one hand, or a longer time period of a lower safety situation (higher accident probability) on the other. The time trade-off scores can then be used, in turn, to calculate QAAPs. QAAPs may be particularly useful in the case of prevention with respect to extremely low probability type accidents.

3.9 Budget Constraint and n-Dimensional Maximization Problem Formulation

Looking at the iso-utility curves in the safety commodity space shown in Figure 3.8, it is obvious that safety management would like to purchase safety commodity bundles as far to the top-right as feasible. The only restriction in doing so is the safety budget at the disposal to safety management. Hence, a budget constraint curve needs to be determined to be able to make an optimal – and realistic – choice regarding the safety commodity bundle. Associated with each commodity is a price. Assume that c03-math-0136 comes at a price c03-math-0137 and c03-math-0138 has a price c03-math-0139. Safety management has a budget of c03-math-0140 euros to divide among the two safety commodities. The cost of the safety commodity bundle c03-math-0141 is c03-math-0142. All budget sets that safety management could conceivably face can then be expressed as c03-math-0143.

The budget constraint is easy to visualize. Safety management will choose from the budget set so as to be on as high an indifference curve as possible (see Figure 3.11).

nfgz011

Figure 3.11 Budget constraint and indifference curves.

In Figure 3.11 the safety commodity bundle c03-math-0144 is the most preferred bundle within reach of the safety budget. This is the safety management's maximization problem for a two-dimensional situation and it is further explained in Section 3.10. The optimal bundle c03-math-0145 can be graphically characterized by the fact that the indifference curve Us, of which c03-math-0146 is a member, lies completely outside the budget set except at point c03-math-0147, where it is tangential to the budget constraint line. In the microeconomic theory literature, this is usually stated as: “At c03-math-0148, the marginal rate of substitution (which is the slope of the indifference curve through c03-math-0149) equals the price ratio (which represents the slope of the budget line).”

This two-dimensional representation allows us to easily carry out and visualize some thought experiments. For example, Figure 3.12(a) shows the result of a budget decrease (if the budget goes down, c03-math-0150 will move toward c03-math-0151), whereas Figure 3.12(b) shows what happens if the price c03-math-0152 of one of the safety goods, c03-math-0153, were to increase (again, c03-math-0154 would move toward c03-math-0155).

nfgz012

Figure 3.12 (a) Effect of decreasing the safety budget on the maximization problem. (b) Effect of increasing c03-math-0156 (price of c03-math-0157) on the maximization problem.

Now assume that there are c03-math-0158 safety goods for investing the safety budget in, instead of only two. Safety commodity bundles are then lists c03-math-0159, and a utility function assigns a number c03-math-0160 to each such list. The safety manager or safety management team's c03-math-0161-dimensional maximization problem can then be stated in the following way:

equation

In order to solve such problems, mathematical techniques such as multivariate calculus and matrix algebra are needed. This falls outside the scope of this book, but the two-dimensional case, which is only a special case of the c03-math-0163-dimensional problem, is discussed further in the next section.

3.10 Determining Optimal Safety Management Preferences within the Budget Constraint for a Two-dimensional Problem

Assume a two-commodity space: safety commodity c03-math-0164 and safety commodity c03-math-0165. For instance, c03-math-0166 represents one specific safety measure and c03-math-0167 represents “all other safety measures.” The incline of the budget line is determined by the respective prices of c03-math-0168 and c03-math-0169. Assume, for instance, that the price of c03-math-0170 is the average price of all the measures composing the parameter. The intersection points with the x-axis and the y-axis, respectively, represent the quantities that safety management could purchase of either c03-math-0171 or c03-math-0172 if the entire budget were spent on this measure. To obtain an optimum point, the indifference curve is shifted in a parallel way until it touches the budget line. This tangent is the optimum c03-math-0173 (see Figure 3.13). The coordinates c03-math-0174 and c03-math-0175 belonging to this tangent represent the number of c03-math-0176 and S2, respectively. It might also be interesting to calculate from these numbers the proportion of c03-math-0177 and c03-math-0178 with respect to the budget. This is possible by simply multiplying by the price per unit and dividing by the total budget.

nfgz013

Figure 3.13 Determining the optimum safety commodity bundle within the budget constraint.

3.11 Conclusions

In this chapter, the foundations of microeconomic theory are applied to the safety research field. It is important to realize that economic principles such as the value function, expected value, utility function, expected utility, and indifference curves are all applicable within the field of safety. Safety utility functions can be drafted, as well as iso-utility curves in the safety commodity space. The safety budget constraint together with the safety iso-utility curves can further be used to solve the safety utility maximization problem, to decide on the optimal choice of a bundle of safety measures within an organization.

References

  1. [1] Fuller, C.W., Vassie, L.H. (2004). Health and Safety Management: Principles and Best Practice. Prentice Hall, Essex.
  2. [2] Garvey, P.R. (2009). Analytical Methods for Risk Management: A Systems Engineering Perspective. Taylor & Francis Group, Boca Raton, FL.
  3. [3] Straffin, P.D. (2003). Game Theory and Strategy. The Mathematical Association of America, Washington, DC.
  4. [4] Von Neumann, J., Morgenstern, O. (1967). Theory of Games and Economic Behaviour. John Wiley & Sons, Inc., New York.
  5. [5] Samuelson, P.A. (1948). Consumption theory in terms of revealed preference. Economica, 15(60), 243–253.
  6. [6] De Borger, B., Van Poeck, A., Bouckaert, J., De Graeve, D. (2013). Algemene Economie 8th edn. De Boeck, Antwerpen.
..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset