Chapter 17

The US Experience: An Interpretation

Abstract

Next we move to the relationships between the trade balance and the foreign exchange value of the dollar and terms of trade. The negative relationship is not anything new or an unexpected result in the context of the traditional view. Where we part company is with the interpretation. While it may be true that a “cheaper dollar” may improve the trade balance, that may not be a desirable outcome if all of the relationships identified in this section hold up. The “cheaper dollar” may be reflecting a deterioration of the terms of trade, in which case an improvement in the trade balance due to a weaker dollar may signal an economic slowdown, higher unemployment, a capital outflow, or a lower relative stock market. We do not think these are desirable changes in these variables. In turn, if our interpretation is correct, the rising dollar and a deteriorating trade balance is a bullish sign—a sign of an improving stock market relative to the rest of the world. So far, we have provided a parsimonious explanation for the various relationships, and that is good for it suggests that our theory, at the very least, has a great deal of explanatory power. The exchange rate-based investment implication of this view of the world is straightforward: follow the money. Underweigh the economies whose exchange rate is expected to depreciate, more specifically those whose terms for trade are expected to deteriorate and overweigh those whose economy is expected to appreciate. An obvious question is how can one tell which economy is going to do what? Our answer is a top-down approach that pays attention to the policy changes. It may point the investors in the right direction. Also, if adjustments are costly, return cycles will be generated. So even if one misses the initial turning point, there will be plenty of time for the astute and studious investor to take advantage of these cycles.

Keywords

economic growth
employment
job creation
stock market performance
terms of trade
trade balance and the economy’s P/E ratio
The trade balance is a commonly used macroeconomic indicator. There are different points of view regarding the information provided by changes in the trade balance of a country. For example, some textbooks view a trade balance deficit as a leakage of domestic aggregate demand. Such a leakage translates into increased demand for foreign goods with a supposedly corresponding multiplier effect. All else the same, had the demand for these foreign goods been channeled into the domestic economy, the overall output and employment levels would have been higher. Also, the trade deficit means that the country is financing its deficit by borrowing and thereby increasing its indebtedness. Viewed from this narrow perspective, a deteriorating trade balance is an undesirable outcome, as it means lower level of output, employment, and higher debt.
A domestic policymaker focused on the improved well-being of the overall economy would take steps to stem the tide and thus take measures to improve the trade balance and stop the leakage or export of jobs and economic activity to the rest of the world, as well as to reduce the country’s ineptness. Some may argue that trade restriction may be what the doctor ordered, yet that is not a commonly followed course of action.
There are the memories of the Great Depression, which some attribute to the Smoot–Hawley tariffs. The use of across-the-board trade restrictions may invite retaliation from other countries. All of this suggests that even if the benefits of the across-the-board restrictions were as the mercantilist suggests, the cost imposed by the retaliatory actions of the other countries may negate any possible benefits. The threat of retaliation is a great deterrent to taking an across-the- board course of action. But tariffs are not the only tool available to those who wish to pursue across-the-board trade actions. There is one additional tool available to their disposal: currency manipulation or exchange rate management. The argument goes as follows: a decline in the exchange rate simultaneously makes the country’s exports cheaper and the country’s imports more expensive. Hence, exports will increase while imports will decline, thereby improving the country’s trade balance.
The inferences derived by the negative relationship between the trade balance and the foreign exchange value of the dollar could easily lead people and policymakers down a bearish path. The obvious implication coming out of this analysis is that to improve the trade balance, the terms of trade (i.e., the dollar) will have to decline substantially. Another fear concerning the decline in the dollar is that if the improvement does not occur fast enough, the fall in the dollar needed to affect the improvement may degenerate into a financial crisis. And this is where many policymakers make a major mistake. Some may be tempted to accelerate the adjustment process by devaluing the currency. We contend that a deliberate devaluation is a major mistake. A monetary devaluation leads to higher inflation. Usually the accompanying economic measures associated with the devaluation lead to slower real GDP growth rate, which in turn leads to an outflow of capital.
The previously mentioned textbook trade balance theory only deals with half of the equation. Under a floating exchange rate, the balance of payments is always zero. The double entry bookkeeping tells us that the trade balance is the mirror image of the capital account. Thus, if a stronger dollar makes imports cheaper and results in a trade deficit, the stronger dollar has to produce a capital inflow. The only way this would make sense is if the stronger dollar is a reflection of higher real returns in the United States vis-a-vis the rest of the world. Hence, we must develop a theory that simultaneously explains both the trade balance and the capital account. We intend to outline such a view in the next few paragraphs.
Also, if the adjustment is costly, the new equilibrium will be reached gradually and market cycles will be observed both in the economy, as well as the price-clearing mechanisms. This is a very important insight. It means that there is an adjustment path as the exchange rate moves from one long-run equilibrium to another. At any point in time, exchange rate changes reflect adjustments to current actions, as well as the gradual adjustment to past shocks. The evidence presented in Fig. 17.1 clearly supports the theory that adjustment costs lead to persistent cycles. This is good news for investors who anticipate and correctly identify these cycles. They will be able to develop strategies to take advantage of the cycles. The implications for policymakers are that their actions may not have the immediate impact on the economy’s international account. It also suggests that it would be a mistake to attribute the current level of exchange rates solely to current shocks.
image
Figure 17.1 Foreign exchange value of the dollar.

Trade Balance: Value or Growth Signal?

Although the trade balance reflects the net level of trade at a specific point in time, in the presence of adjustment costs, the trade balance may reflect the effects of past actions as well as future expectations. One simple way to explain our views of the trade balance is to draw a parallel between a country and a household and/or a publicly traded company. In all three cases, we have ongoing concerns that focus not only on the present, but also on the future.
In general, household expenditures will be based on their lifetime income or net worth. Early on in its life cycle, through education, the members of the household may increase their future earning power. If the net present value of the increase in future income exceeds the cost of educating, the household will invest in human capital. The household net worth increases relative to its current income. Since expenditures are a function of the net present value of future income, the household expenditures exceed their income during the early years. The households finance the excess consumption (i.e., its trade deficit in goods and services) through their borrowing (i.e., a capital inflow finances their investment in human capital). In the future, when their human capital and earnings power rises, the investment and borrowing used to finance past consumption will be repaid. Late in the life cycle, as the household is at or near retirement, its earned income declines. During these years, the household will spend well above its earned income. The household will be depleting its net worth during those years.
Similarly, if a company faces great future opportunities, it may choose some external financing to achieve its goals faster and maximize shareholder value. In this case, the “growth company” borrows money or sells new equities to finance its growth. On the other hand, if the company finds itself with a stash of cash and no great investment opportunities, returning its cash to its investors may be the proper policy. At this point, one may argue that the company has ceased to be a growth stock and has become a value stock. The lower growth prospect will also produce a lower Price Earnings (P/E) ratio.
The parallels between the household and a country or a business are straightforward. The gap between expenditures and production will be met through the trade balance, which is financed by capital inflows. Similarly, a growing country may find borrowing worthwhile. If the increase exceeds the cost, the investment is a worthwhile one and the country’s net worth to income ratio (i.e. P/E ratio) will rise as the trade balance worsens. Finally, when the country matures past its peak, it will maintain its standard of living by selling assets. It will finance its excess consumption over its “earned income” through asset sales. During this time, the trade deficit will be accompanied by a declining P/E ratio.
Whether we use the household or company analogy, we have developed two distinct alternative explanations of why a trade balance deficit may occur. The question is which one of the two alternatives is the relevant one to the US situation. One simple way to distinguish between the growth and value stocks or the stage of life is to focus on the economy’s P/E ratio. The household net worth to disposable income ratio will rise during growth stages and decline during value stages. Using the household borrowing analogy, if the money borrowed is invested and it earns a higher rate of return, household net worth will rise. The borrowed money finances investments that will result in a higher level of output and employment. Fig. 17.2 shows the household net worth as a percent of disposable personal income.
image
Figure 17.2 Household net worth as a percent of disposable personal income.
The data shows an uptrend that is not a smooth one, suggesting that there are periods of relative economic slowdown where the United States does not behave like a growth stock. The policymakers’ quest is to find the appropriate policy mix that prevents or minimizes the “value”—like periods of the US economy. The data also points to an upward trend suggesting that, secularly, the economy is behaving like a growth company. If that is the case, the trade deficit is a good thing. It means that capital is flowing in because it can earn a higher risk adjusted rate of return in the United States. This evidence contradicts the mercantilist view of the world that equates the trade deficit with an undesirable and unprofitable increased ineptness. We argue here that the foreign capital has financed part of the US expansion and prosperity, a good thing and a desirable one.

The Trade Balance and the Economy’s Price Earnings Ratio

The relationship between the inverse of the household net worth and the trade balance as a percent of disposable personal income is a tight one (Fig. 17.3). The approach outlined here provides some insight into the potential impact of different policy actions on the trade balance and, by inference, the terms of trade or real exchange rate. Our framework suggests two alternative ways of improving our trade balance. One is to reduce the US economy’s P/E ratio, while the other is to increase the rest of the world’s P/E ratio. The former approach, more likely than not, is a bearish one. In contrast, the latter is quite bullish. If the rest of the world adopts progrowth policies, capital will flow their way and their trade surpluses will decline and could even become trade deficits if they are successful enough. This would truly be a case of a rising tide lifting all boats. The world economy would soar.
image
Figure 17.3 Disposable personal income as a share of net worth versus the trade balance as a percent of GDP.
Looking at Fig. 17.2, we notice a few inflection points in the economy’s P/E ratio. It is apparent that once the Reagan tax policy was fully implemented, the P/E ratio rose and reached a new plateau and essentially remained there until 1995, when the Republicans took over Congress. Then in 2000, amidst the Y2K concern and the technology bubble bursting, the P/E ratio took a major hit. In time it recovered and got past its pre-1995 peak. The economy took another hit during the bursting of the housing bubble and the global financial meltdown, wherein again the data points to a complete recovery. The ratio of household net worth to income is once again at or near an all-time high. Notice the correlation of household net worth to income ratio and the policy inflection. We believe that the correlation is a causal one going from policy changes to the economy’s P/E ratio, that is, the household net worth to GNP ratio. If that is the case and adjustment is costly, our framework can anticipate the future path of these variables as the federal government alters its policy mix, a useful insight for top-down global macroinvestors.
Our explanation requires two distinct assumptions. One is that in the long run (by this we mean that the economy will approach its long-run equilibrium) PPP will be restored. Shocks will give rise to temporary disturbances that push the economy away from its old equilibrium and into a new one. If the world we live in were frictionless, all adjustment would be instantaneous. Unfortunately, that is not the case. Adjustment costs mean that it may take some time for the economy to reach a new equilibrium. The path the economy takes to reach the new equilibrium depends on numerous factors. Nevertheless, at any point in time, the value of the exchange rate may reflect adjustments to previous and current market conditions. If one believes our interpretation of major inflection points, it is easy to see two cycles of appreciation. One begins around 1983–84 when the Reagan tax rates were being implemented, and the other during 1995 when the Republicans took over Congress. As the economy recovers from the financial crisis and wealth traces hold ground, is it possible that a third cycle may be in the offing? The big question is what are the policies that will take us there?
Getting back to the previous two peaks, there are two different explanations that tell the same story. Early on, the US economy behaved like a growth stock. Investors, both domestic and international, flocked to the United States; the capital inflow produced a higher stock market. Early on, as net worth increased relative to disposable income, we saw the US trade balance worsen (Fig. 17.3).
The United States outperformed the rest of the world. As investors tried to acquire dollars to invest in the United States, the dollar appreciated above its purchasing power parity value. Over time, as investment continued, the rate of return in new investments declined and eventually the rates of return returned to their long-run equilibrium. PPP was once again restored. Since the price rule essentially eliminates monetary disturbances as the source of exchange rate fluctuations, it follows that the bulk of the fluctuations in the dollar will reflect the US terms of trade or relative rates of return. Thus, early on as the rate of return increases, the dollar appreciates. However, if PPP is to be restored, the dollar will have to experience a round trip. More important, the price rule insures that the fluctuations in the dollar will not alter in any significant way the underlying inflation rate. In both cases we see the exchange rate behaves like an inverted “V” (Fig. 17.1).

Trade, Employment, and Growth

Double entry bookkeeping requires that a country’s net exports equal the difference between its savings and investment rate. That is, a country whose savings rate exceeds its investment rate will be a net exporter. Countries with a trade deficit finance the net imports of goods and services by borrowing from abroad. However, the fact that a country is a net borrower or a net lender does not provide any information about the level of its savings and/or investment.
For example, a country may have a double-digit savings rate, say the highest in the world, and yet be a net borrower. All that this situation requires is that the investment rates exceed the country’s savings rate. One simple explanation for this scenario is that the economy is full of opportunities. Income and wealth may be rising. If the former rises faster, then the savings rate will rise. However, since wealth is rising, consumption also rises. Hence if the income does not rise fast enough to keep up with the increase in wealth and consumption, the savings rate will decline, and the trade balance will worsen. This is the scenario that we have in mind for the United States during the 1980s and 1990s. Fig. 17.3 shows a negative relationship between the trade balance and the ratio of net worth to GDP. China’s scenario, as we have discussed elsewhere, is a bit different, with income rising faster than wealth, and it leads to an increase in savings. The higher wealth leads to higher consumption. Finally, if the increase in savings exceeds the investment opportunities, the country will be a net saver, that is, exporter.
Now in a forward-looking world with well-developed capital markets, wealth is related to discounted value of income. Hence we expect to see a positive relationship between rising wealth and income growth. More importantly, there is another implication for the relationship between the trade balance and economic growth and/or employment. Unanticipated increases in economic growth that lead to an increase in the net worth to GDP ratio should result in a deterioration of the trade balance and thus produce a negative relationship between the trade balance and economic growth and employment. Fig. 17.4 shows the relationship between the trade balance and employment growth, while Fig. 17.5 shows the relationship between employment growth and real GDP growth. Figure 17.5 shows that the two variables are closely correlated as expected. Higher real GDP growth is closely correlated with a higher employment growth and vice versa. In contrast, Fig. 17.4 identifies an interesting relationship between the trade balance and employment growth. Notice the clear negative relationship between the spikes in the trade balance and employment growth, results that are counterintuitive in the context of the textbook traditional view. However, we have a simple explanation: an increase in output and employment also points to increased opportunities in the US economy, hence a capital inflow and that, in turn, means a deterioration of the trade balance. The relationships are not causal, but identified as correlations. However, it raises a warning flag. Protectionist attempts to improve the trade balance may lead to a lower GDP and lower employment. The best example of this type of policy mistake is none other than the Smoot–Hawley tariffs and their impact during the 1930s.
image
Figure 17.4 Trade balance as a percent of GDP versus employment growth.
image
Figure 17.5 Real GDP and employment growth.

Do Exports Create Jobs? What About Imports?

Fig. 17.4 shows a negative correlation between employment growth and trade deficits. Put another way, the data does not support the mercantilist view that trade deficits mean a net export of jobs. That is a very narrow and static view of the world that is not supported by the empirical evidence.
Mercantilists argue that exports create jobs and that imports cost jobs. While the statement may be true in a ceteris paribus world, not everything else is constant, in a mutatis mutandis world that need not be the case. As we have already shown, the data suggests that an accelerating US economy leads to higher employment and a deterioration of the US trade balance.
We know from the lifecycle consumption theory that, on average, all wealth will be consumed. Hence, all income will be spent. This means that the lifecycle budget constraint requires that the value of exports and imports over the lifecycle be equal. In addition, since the world is a closed economy, the sum of all imports has to add up to the sum of all exports. The world trade balance is zero. There is no intergalactic trade. Put another way, the lifecycle trade balance has to be zero. The net savings over the lifecycle has to be zero. A policy that promotes exports has to automatically promote imports, and no net jobs are created by promoting exports (Fig. 17.6). Both imports and exports tend to move together as the lifecycle theory predicts. Thus, job creation should not focus on the trade balance. In fact, policies aimed at promoting jobs and growth will, in the short run, lead to a deterioration of the trade balance. Attempts to improve the trade balance, promote exports, and/or restrict imports would only distort the economy and thereby retard economic growth.
image
Figure 17.6 US imports and exports as a percent of GDP.

Economic Growth, the Trade Balance, and the Stock Market Performance

Up to this point enough relationships between the US household net worth versus the trade balance as a percent of GDP (Fig. 17.3), employment growth, and the trade balance (Fig. 17.4) have been accumulated. We also showed the close relationship between employment growth and real GDP growth (Fig. 17.5). Given the high correlation between the employment and real GDP growth rate and the relationship between the employment growth and the trade balance, we can surmise a similar relationship between real GDP growth and the trade balance as a percent of GDP.
Next we explore the relationship between the trade balance and the US share of the world real GDP and the stock market Morgan Stanley Capital Index (MSCI) index. The relationships reported in Figs. 17.7 and 17.8 are consistent with the previous relationships reported. The common element between the two figures is the negative correlation between the spikes in the two variables included in the figures. This suggests that an increase in the US share of the world income is correlated with a deterioration of the trade balance. However, the US share of the world income can only rise if the United States grows faster than the rest of the world. The result for Fig. 17.8 is also similar. An increase in the US share of the world equity market is associated with a deterioration of the trade balance. Since the US share of the world’s equity markets can only result when the US market valuation rises faster than the rest of the world, we can say that the an improvement in the US relative growth rate and relative stock market returns are associated with a deterioration of the trade balance. The correlations reported in Figs. 17.7 and 17.8 say more than that. They suggest that there is a positive correlation between the real GDP growth rate and the stock returns. It suggests that there is a positive correlation between the United States outperforming the World real GDP growth rate and the United States outperforming the world stock market returns. Fig. 17.9 confirms what Figs. 17.7 and 17.8 implied.
image
Figure 17.7 US trade balance as a percent of GDP versus the US GDP as a percent of the rest of the world.
image
Figure 17.8 US trade balance as a percent of GDP versus the ratio of the US to the rest of the world MSCI index.
image
Figure 17.9 The US GDP as a percent of the rest of the world versus the ratio of the US to the rest of the world MSCI index.
A trade deficit means that we have a capital inflow; we are borrowing from our trading partners. Pundits worry that we are living beyond our means and that our best days are behind us or that we are eating our way into the poorhouse. If that was the case, we would expect to see the market anticipate this and decline relative to the rest of the world whenever the trade balance worsens. The implication here is clear. It predicts a negative relationship between trade deficits and the US stock market relative to the rest of the world. Yet that is not what the data says.
There is another, alternative interpretation: the reason for borrowing is that there are great investment opportunities, and, by borrowing, we take advantage of these opportunities. Put another way, better days are ahead of us. The higher future return allows us to pay for the amount borrowed without sacrificing current consumption. The higher investment returns attract capital, and as the market anticipates the higher returns, valuations will rise and the United States will outperform the rest of the world. Hence, not only US investors, but also foreign investors will want to take advantage of the opportunities in the United States. Advocates of the “better days ahead” alternative theory predict a negative relationship between the trade balance, stock markets, real GDP, and employment growth relative performances. Figs. 17.417.7and 17.8 clearly support our views and contradict the alternative interpretation. As we argued, there is a distinctive and clear negative relationship between the trade balance as a percent of GDP and the relative stock market performance measured by the ratio of the United States versus the MSCI Rest of the World Indices. That is not all. As capital flows in, the demand for dollars will rise and a dollar appreciation is to be expected.

The Exchange Rate and Terms of Trade

To close the circle, we need to discuss the relationship between real GDP growth and the different variables. We have already established the negative relationship between real GDP and the trade balance as a percent of GDP. We also argued that as economic opportunity improves, capital will flow into the country and that, in turn, leads to a net increase in the demand for the US dollar. As a result, we expect to observe a positive relationship between real GDP growth and the foreign exchange value of the dollar, due to capital inflow, and to the relative stock market returns, due to the improving investment opportunities. Fig. 17.9 presents some clear evidence of a positive correlation between an improving relative stock market performance and the US real GDP growth rate. One striking result is reported in Fig. 17.10. Notice the close correlation between the US share of the world’s GDP and the foreign exchange value of the dollar. At first one may be surprised by the results, but there is a simple monetarist explanation for this. If the demand for money is relatively stable, and the income elasticity of the demand for money is one, i.e. the demand for real balance is proportional to the income level in the country, then it follows that the price level will be proportional to the inverse of the income level. Therefore the nominal exchange rate, being the ratio of two price levels, will reflect the ratio of the two regions’ output, that is the United States and rest of the world income levels. Fig. 17.11 shows the US share of the world GDP and the terms of trade. Notice that the relationship is not as close as the one reported in Fig. 17.10. The conclusion being that the terms of trade contain different information set than the nominal exchange rate, that is, the US dollar index.
image
Figure 17.10 The US GDP as a percent of the rest of the world versus the foreign exchange value of the dollar.
image
Figure 17.11 The US GDP as a percent of the rest of the world versus the terms of trade.
Next, we move to the relationships between the trade balance and the foreign exchange value of the dollar and terms of trade. We also examined the relationship between the US stock market as a share of the world market and the dollar index as well as the terms of trade. Unfortunately as Fig. 17.12 shows, if there is a negative correlations between the US dollar and the trade balance as a percent of GDP It is a fairly weak one. A much stronger correlation can be found between the terms of trade and the trade balance (Fig. 17.13). These results lend support to the view that it is real factors that determine the changes in the trade balance. As we have already mentioned, sometimes the exchange rate reflects changes in the terms of trade, and at other times, it reflects changes in the relative rates of inflation, or put another way, it reflects monetary shocks. This may explain the weak negative relationship. The monetary shocks are noise that obfuscate the true relationship. The negative relationship is not anything new or an unexpected result in the context of the traditional view. Where we part company is with the interpretation. While it may be true that a “cheaper dollar” may improve the trade balance, that may not be a desirable outcome if all of the relationships identified in this section hold up. The “cheaper dollar” may be reflecting a deterioration of the terms of trade in which case an improvement in the trade balance due to a weaker dollar may signal an economic slowdown, higher unemployment, a capital outflow, or a lower relative stock market. We do not think these are desirable changes in these variables. In turn, if our interpretation is correct, the rising dollar and a deteriorating trade balance is a bullish sign. It is a sign of an improving stock market relative to the rest of the world. Fig. 17.14 shows that, as expected, there is a positive correlation between the US dollar and the US relative stock performance. However Fig. 17.15 shows that the relationship is much stronger when the terms of trade replace the foreign exchange value of the dollar.
image
Figure 17.12 The trade balance as a percent of GDP versus the foreign exchange value of the dollar.
image
Figure 17.13 The trade balance as a percent of GDP versus the terms of trade.
image
Figure 17.14 The ratio of the US to rest of the world MSCI index versus the foreign exchange value of the dollar.
image
Figure 17.15 The ratio of the US to rest of the world MSCI index versus the terms of trade.
So far, we have provided a parsimonious explanation for the various relationships, and that is good for it suggests that our theory, at the very least, has a great deal of explanatory power. The exchange rate-based investment implication of this view of the world is straightforward: follow the money. Underweigh the economies whose exchange rate is expected to depreciate. More specifically, follow those whose terms for trade are expected to deteriorate and overweigh those whose economy is expected to appreciate. An obvious question is how can one tell which economy is going to do what? Our answer is that a top-down approach that pays attention to the policy changes, weather changes, and innovations may point the investors in the right direction. Also if adjustments are costly, returns cycles will be generated. So even if one misses the intimal turning point, there will be plenty of time for the astute and studious investor to take advantage of these cycles.
..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset