Chapter 6

The Competitive Economic Environment: Lessons From the States

Abstract

If one thinks of the United States as one large economy in the global economy, the parallels also apply. Increases in the tax rates will elicit a capital outflow and an outmigration. The mobile factors will move to arbitrage the differences in tax rates. Worse yet, given the progressivity of the tax code, the people who will leave the state will be the very successful with very high income. Add to this an expansion of the social safety net and other programs, and as it was with the states’ data, the social programs will be a magnet for lower income people who qualify for these programs. The overall migration away from the high tax states to the other states documented by the data is in line with the competitive environment framework that we have outlined. More importantly, if the high tax rates are the result of profligate spending, whether in large benefits to public employees or expansive social programs, these policies may attract lower income taxpayers who could take advantage of these mean-tested programs. The result may be an outflow of taxpayers with a high taxable income combined with an inflow of taxpayers of lower taxable income. Some may call that a tax-driven “brain drain.” The policy and investment implications are clear. Tax rates changes, the social safety net, and other programs will alter the attractiveness of an economy. The analysis shows that different policies attract different factors. Politicians should be careful to design policies that attract the factors of production that the electorate desires and the economy needs. Keeping a tab on the policies relative to the actions of the neighboring states or for that matter of other countries in the world, one may be able to identify trends that benefit the local factors or for that matter the foreign factors. Either way one has a profitable investment insight.

Keywords

brain drain
business location
migration
Right to Work
state competitive environment
tax competition
free trade and mobility
Much has been written about the impact of tax rates on the aggregate economy, as well as the states’ relative performance. While political campaigns in the United States are focused on federal tax policy and whether the top personal income tax rate should be increased or not, we believe that the states’ experiences have much to teach us about what happens when tax rates are changed. The parallel between the United States and the world economy is an obvious one. The United States consists of 50 separate state economies and factors of production, and as a result of the interstate commerce clause, the states enjoy free trade of goods and services and the factors of production enjoy freedom of movement. Thus, businesses and people can relocate anywhere within and across the states. The choice of location may be based on a multitude of factors, such as climate or other endowments. We contend that a state’s fiscal policies can also alter these conditions and make relocation to their jurisdiction more or less attractive. Hence, the state and local fiscal policies can become a key driver of the economic well-being of a state, a significant driver of the state revenue coffers, as well as an important determinant of the internal migration patterns within the United States.
At the national level, the political debate regarding the impact of increases in tax rates is focused on the aggregate labor supply elasticities. We contend that the relevant elasticities are larger than the ones cited in the academic literature. One of the reasons for this conclusion is the fact that most people acknowledge and are aware that earners can move taxable income between different years, as well as change the timing of charitable contributions and capital gains realization. In addition, some taxpayers are able to convert earned income into capital gains, that is, the carried interest in private equity.
Interestingly, these measures, without affecting the aggregate labor supply, either reduce the tax base or the marginal tax rate to which income is subjected. Another effect is simply relocation or moving away from the tax jurisdiction. Outsourcing and outright migration are just two examples of how the tax base of a particular tax jurisdiction can change, even though the supply per worker remains the same. Migration and outsourcing reduces the number of workers and factories and thus the tax base of the tax jurisdiction where companies were previously located, while it increases the tax base of the jurisdiction where they relocate.
Higher tax rates collect more per dollar taxed. However, the base reduction due to avoidance, migration, or simply lower aggregate supply per unit worker means that there will be fewer dollars to be taxed. So whether tax revenues increase or decrease depends on whether the reduction in the tax base is large enough to offset the tax rate increase.
The anecdotal evidence suggests that the sensitivity of the states’ revenue collection to tax rate changes is much greater than the proponents of tax rate increases claim or believe. In Oklahoma, Republican Governor Frank Keating and then-Democrat Brad Henry cut the income tax rates to 5.25% from 7%, and revenues kept rising. Maryland’s Governor Martin O’Malley raised taxes in 2007, saying that he could balance the budget by taxing high-income people. His strategy did not work very well. The number of millionaires in the state fell sharply. Some of this was due to the recession, but some of it was also due to migration out of the state. Then, to close the budget gap, the governor proposed more taxes, this time on the middle class.
In general, states with some of the highest income tax rates—Maryland and Illinois—have had the toughest time staying out of the red. In contrast, states with no personal income tax—New Hampshire, Tennessee, and Florida—manage to balance their budgets.

The States’ Competitive Environment

The relative performance and the changing fortunes of the high-tax and low-tax states does not bode well for the supporters of tax increases. The issue is how significant the impact of tax rate changes is on the tax base (labor supply per worker), tax minimization and avoidance (by altering the timing of income realization), conversion (from one form of income into another), and relocation of factors (out of the tax jurisdiction) or businesses to lower tax states (domestic corporate inversions). The sensitivity of the tax base to tax rate changes may be greater than estimates made by simply using the labor supply elasticities or some other narrowly defined measure. Those estimates are ignoring the outsourcing and evasion effects on the tax base.
Time and distance also enter into the relocation decision. Take the case of a potential migrant. The larger the migration gains, the more likely the factors of production will migrate. The longer the factors’ horizon, the easier it will be to amortize the cost of migration. This argument suggests that the supply elasticities increase with time. The further the factors have to move, all else the same, the higher the transportation costs, the less likely a factor is to move to that location. The insight here is that while most people consider neighboring states to be their direct competitors, the fact remains that all other locations across the world are alternatives that any mobile factor may or should consider when contemplating a move out of state. It is a mistake to focus on the local economy as if it were a closed economy. Hence we need to develop a framework that considers all these possibilities where all localities are in competition.
One important implication of this is that the immobile factor bears the full burden of economic policy, both the good and the bad. When good things happen in a state and transportation costs are reduced, the after-tax returns of land, the fixed or immobile factor increase disproportionately. Similarly, when the transportation costs increase, land will also bear a disproportionate impact.

The States’ Income Tax Rates as a Proxy for Their Competitive Environment

We argue that trade and factor mobility result in the equalization of the gross of tax factor returns across state boundaries. Hence a tax increase in one state results in a lower after-tax rate of return in that state. However, that alone is not enough to determine whether the factor will move across state borders. Our framework suggests a simple answer: as the gross of tax returns are the same, all one needs to know is the differences in tax rates between the state in question and the rest of the world. Therefore, by understanding and anticipating changes of the transportation costs, that is, the differences in tax rates across state boundaries, one may be able to anticipate the changes in the differences in expected returns and correlation between the rates of return of the immobile factors across the different state borders. It is these differences in correlation and expected returns that give rise to the states’ relative economic performance.
Using the top personal income tax rates for each of the states in 2017 and 2008, we separated the states into one of four groups: no state income tax rates, high state income tax rates, rising state income tax rates, and other or “average” tax rates. Using the data for each of the states reported in Table 6.1, we grouped the net migration information into one of the several groups.

Table 6.1

Top Personal Income Tax Rates 2017 and 2008, and Right-to-Work Designation
State 2017 2008
Top income tax rates Top income tax rates Right to Work
Alabama 5.00% 5.00% 1953
Alaska 0.00% 0.00%
Arizona 4.54% 4.54% 1946
Arkansas 6.90% 7.00% 1944
California 13.30% 10.30%
Colorado 4.63% of federal 4.63% of federal
Connecticut 6.99% 5.00%
Delaware 6.60% 5.95%
District of Columbia 8.95% 8.50%
Florida 0 0 1944
Georgia 6.00% 6.00% 1947
Hawaii 8.25% 8.25%
Idaho 7.40% 7.80% 1985
Illinois 3.75% of federal 3% of federal
Indiana 3.23% of federal 3.4% of federal 2012
Iowa 8.98% 8.98% 1947
Kansas 4.60% 6.45% 1958
Kentucky 6.00% 6.00% 2017
Louisiana 6.00% 6.00% 1976
Maine 10.15% 8.50%
Maryland 5.75% 5.75%
Massachusetts 5.60% 12.00%
Michigan 4.25% of federal AGI 4.35% of federal AGI 2013
Minnesota 9.85% 7.85%
Missouri 6.00% 6.00%
Mississippi 5.00% 5.00% 1954
Montana 6.90% 6.90%
Nebraska 6.84% 6.84% 1946
Nevada 0 0 1952
New Hampshire 5.00% 5.00%
New Jersey 8.97% 8.97%
New Mexico 4.90% 5.30%
New York 8.82% 6.85%
North Carolina 5.499% 8.000% 1947
North Dakota 2.90% 5.54% 1948
Ohio 4.997% 6.555%
Oklahoma 5.00% 5.65% 2001
Oregon 9.90% 9.00%
Pennsylvania 3.07% 3.07%
Rhode Island 5.99% 9.90%
South Carolina 7.00% 7.00% 1954
South Dakota 0.00% 0.00%
Tennessee 5.00% 6.00% 1947
Texas 0.00% 0.00%
Utah 5.00% 5.00% 1955
Vermont 8.95% 9.50% 1947
Virginia 5.75% 5.75%
Washington 0.00% 0.00%
West Virginia 6.50% 6.50% 2016
Wisconsin 7.65% 6.75% 2015
Wyoming 0.00% 0.00% 1963


Source: Tax Foundation and the National Right-to-Work Committee.

The listing for each of the tax groups is as follows:
  • States with no state income tax rates: Alaska, Florida, Nevada, South Dakota, Texas, Washington, and Wyoming.
  • States with high state personal income tax rates: California and Connecticut, the District of Columbia, Hawaii, Illinois, Idaho, Iowa, Maine, Minnesota, New Jersey, New York, Oregon, South Carolina, and Vermont.
  • States with the low personal income tax rates: Alabama, Arizona, Mississippi, New Hampshire, New Mexico, North Dakota, Oklahoma, Pennsylvania, Tennessee, and Utah.
  • States with increase in the top tax rates: California, Connecticut, Delaware, District of Columbia, Illinois, Maine, Minnesota, New York, Oregon, and Wisconsin.
  • States with a decrease in the top personal income tax rates: Idaho, Kansas, New Mexico, North Carolina, North Dakota, Ohio, Oklahoma, Rhode Island, Tennessee, and Vermont.
  • The other or “average” states: Arkansas, Colorado, Georgia, Indiana, Kansas, Kentucky, Louisiana, Maryland, Massachusetts, Michigan, Missouri, Montana, Nebraska, North Carolina, Ohio, Oklahoma, Rhode Island, Virginia, and West Virginia.
There are a couple of points that need to be made regarding our classification. First, notice the overlap between the high tax rate states and the states with rising rates during the period. Second, the grouping is based on events from 2008 through 2017. Thus, it includes the aftermath of the financial crisis.

The Evidence: The Changing Competitive Environment

Fortunately, there is a way that allows us to test the basic hypothesis that tax rates do matter and that migration is one way to arbitrage the differences in the after-tax rates of return. The Internal Revenue Service (IRS) publishes information on annual state-to-state migration. Although the data is readily available, it is presented in a cumbersome way and it requires a bit of work to manipulate the information. Then there is the issue that the migration is based on returns filed and, as such, it may not capture some of the migration at the lower end of the income scale or people who do not file a return. Using the IRS data, we have summarized the migration inflows, outflows, and nonmigration statistics of the states grouped by the previously mentioned tax level classification. As we are looking at the total inflow and outflow by state, the grouping will include some double counting. That is there may be some migration from one state to another in the same grouping and while technically we should remove it, which is not possible, using the broad data used to construct Table 6.2.

Table 6.2

2008–2015 US Migration Across States
States income tax rates classification Nonmigrants Inflows Outflows Net Inflows
Returns Households AGI per return Returns Households AGI per return Returns Households AGI per return Returns Households AGI per return
High tax rates states 265,047,198 575,732,909 69,016.09 5,883,209 10,335,157 54,279.59 6,583,482 11,881,296 59,266.39 −700,273 −1,546,139 −4986.80
Middle tax rates states 266,478,783 575,681,282 60,301.08 7,356,005 13,917,055 47,936.07 7,695,438 14,464,480 49,849.83 −339,433 −547,425 −1,913.76
Low tax rates states 107,793,819 236,636,834 57,032.06 3,010,989 5,852,434 47,849.31 3,170,276 6,109,980 46,197.62 −159,287 −257,546 1651.69
No income tax states 129,052,291 280,378,754 60,006.63 4,306,928 8,220,598 57,562.94 3,879,809 7,294,044 46,899.77 427,119 926,554 10,663.17
All states 768,372,091 1,668,429,779 62,799.23 20,557,131 38,325,244 51,755.73 21,329,005 39,749,800 51,676.90 −771,874 −1,424,556 78.83

The level of state income tax rates: the information presented in Table 6.2 is quite intriguing and supportive of our underlying assumption. The last row of the table reports the aggregate data for the United States. Notice that the average adjusted gross income (AGI) per return is $51,755.73 for the inflows and $51676.9 for the outflows from the states. The net difference between the two is $78.83, an insignificant amount. This information may lead some to suggest that in the aggregate there is no net gain from migration from one place to another. Yet as one looks to the different groups, the story is quite different. The first thing to notice is the relationship between the net inflows and the tax classification. The data shows the largest outflows for the states with the highest tax rates. The outflow is larger in both absolute terms, as well as a percent of the nonmigrant population. As we move down the tax groups from the highest toward the average and low tax states, the outflow diminishes and turns into a net inflow for the states with no income tax rates. The highest tax rate states are losing population at the fastest rate, while the no income tax states are gaining. The data suggests a clear correlation between the states tax rates and the net migration across state lines.
Another interesting piece of information is presented in the last column of Table 6.2. It shows the difference between the average AGI per return between the inflows to that of the outflows experienced by the groups of states. For the states with the highest tax rates, the difference is −$4986.80. Yet as one moves down the column toward the states with lower tax rates, the negative differential narrows and turns positive for the group of lower tax rates, as well as those with no income tax. These results show that for the higher tax rate states the income of the inflows or immigrants is lower than that of the outflow or the people leaving the state, while the reverse is true for the lower tax rate states.
Given the progressivity of the tax code, combined with a progressive taxation in some states, it follows that the higher income taxpayers will be the ones with the largest potential gains from leaving the high tax area. Under a highly progressive structure, there may not be a meaningful tax arbitrage opportunity for the lower income taxpayers. More important, if the high tax rates are the result of profligate spending, whether in large benefits to public employees or expansive, and in some cases mean-tested, social programs, these policies may attract lower income taxpayers who could take advantage of these mean-tested programs. The end result may be an outflow of taxpayers with a high taxable income combined with an inflow of taxpayers of lower taxable income. Some may call that a tax-driven “brain drain.”
The changes in state income tax rates reported in Table 6.3 tell the same qualitative story. The outflow is greater in both absolute, as well as in percentage term of the state’s populations for those states experiencing an increase in the state income tax rates. Again, as before, the income of those leaving the rising tax rate states is higher than those coming into the state. In contrast, for those the states with declining tax rates, the income is approximately the same, while the net flow is very close to a wash. This data suggests that the outflow from the rising rate states is more than likely to go not necessarily to the states with declining tax rates, but to those with the lowest tax rates.

Table 6.3

Migration in States With Rising and Falling Income Tax Rates
Nonmigrants Inflows Outflows Net inflows
Returns Households AGI per return Returns Households AGI per return Returns Households AGI per return Returns Households AGI per return
States with rising tax rates 232,581,084 504,458,452 68,888.14 4,731,844 8,135,998 54,183.53 5,397,210 9,655,252 60,119.28 −665,366 −1,519,254 −5,935.75
States with falling tax rates 99,993,695 234,352,149 55,758.72 2,884,756 6,075,056 46,712.25 2,946,227 6,163,984 46,350.94 −61,471 −88,928 361.30

The Right to Work principle affirms the right of every American to work for a living without being compelled to belong to a union. A Right to Work law guarantees that no person can be compelled, as a condition of employment, to join or not to join, nor to pay dues to a labor union. Section 14(b) of the Taft-Hartley Act affirms the right of states to enact Right to Work laws. Some studies have documented the fact that Right to Work states have greater economic vitality; official Department of Labor statistics show, with faster growth in manufacturing and nonagricultural jobs, lower unemployment rates and fewer work stoppages. Under these conditions, one would expect a net inflow of workers into the Right to Work states. The net migration patterns into the states with and without Right to Work legislation can be found in Table 6.4. The results reported in the last three columns tell a familiar story. The Right to Work states are gaining populations while the non-Right to Work states are losing population. While the income of the inflows into the non-Right to Work is a bit smaller than that of the outflow, that differential reverses sign and is much more pronounced for the Right to Work states. The inflows have a higher income to the tune of $2395.378. Hence not only are the Right to Work states gaining taxpayers, the ones they are gaining have a higher income than the ones they are losing. Brain drain anyone?

Table 6.4

Migration and Right-to-Work States
Nonmigrants Inflows Outflows Net inflows
Returns Households AGI per return Returns Households AGI per return Returns Households AGI per return Returns Households AGI Per Return
Not right-to-Work 588,176,827 1,264,383,357 65,211.4 14,458,987 26,260,381 54,221.4 15,420,868 28,048,500 54,804.3 −961,881 −1,788,119 −582.86
Right-to-Work 180,195,264 404,046,422 54,925.8 6,098,144 12,064,863 45,909.5 5,908,137 11,701,300 43,514.1 190,007 363,563 2,395.38

If one takes the Right to Work laws as a proxy for government intervention, regulations, and other rigidities, the data show that states that are less regulated and more sympathetic to free enterprise (i.e., the Right to Work states), gained population and increased their tax base. The opposite holds true for the states with no Right to Work laws. The one issue that we have yet to focus is whether there is any interaction between the states’ tax rate policies and the Right to Work in determining and affecting a state economic environment.

The Interaction Among States’ Migration, State Income Tax Rates, and Right to Work

Information regarding the interaction between the migration patterns, the state’s income tax rates, and whether a state is a Right to Work state is reported in Table 6.5. The top panel reports information on the states classified as high tax rate states. Notice that this group is then subdivided into Right to Work, rising tax rates, average tax rates, and falling tax rates. The relevant information for purposes of the current discussion is reported in the last column of the table. Upon inspection of the data a clear pattern emerges. Within the high tax rate states, the following groups of states for whom the net inflows or net immigration show a positive number. That is the incoming people as a group experience a net gain and thus show a positive number; see the last column of Table 6.5. The states with population and income gains are either states located in: Right to Work states or states with falling tax rates and/or “average” tax rates. Notice also that the high tax rates states lost population to all the groups except for the Right to Work states with “average” income tax rates.

Table 6.5

Interaction between State Migration Patterns, State Income Tax Rates, and Right-to-Work Laws
Nonmigrants Inflows Outflows
No. of States Returns Households AGI per return Returns Households AGI per return Returns Households AGI per return
High tax rates 14 296,786,958 649,000,562 67,560.93 5,883,209 10,335,157 54,279.59 6,583,482 11,881,296 59,266.39
    Right to Work 4 94,594,361 200,955,394 67,799.43 1,475,563 2,455,806 57,718.52 1,813,595 3,160,480 65,018.83
    Right to Work and falling tax rates 2 3,3764,781 76,625,251 54,914.28 207,292 407,182 46,288.48 214,422 409,392 42,334.82
    Rising tax rates 8 214,627,195 466,277,767 69,661.37 4,401,268 7,528,618 54,530.78 4,983,411 8,915,958 60,853.46
    “Average” tax rates 4 48,394,982 106,097,544 67,069.12 1,274,649 2,399,357 54,711.81 1,385,649 2,555,946 56,178.63
    “Average” tax rates and Right-to-Work 2 21,430,655 48,223,724 54,271.01 636,710 1,240,945 48,911.01 542,811 1,028,586 41,974.15
    “Average” tax rates and Not Right to Work 2 26,964,327 57,873,820 77,240.78 637,939 1,158,412 60,501.43 842,838 1,527,360 65,326.71
    Falling tax rates 2 33,764,781 76,625,251 54,914.28 207,292 407,182 46,288.48 214,422 409,392 42,334.82
    Falling rates and Right to Work 2 33,764,781 76,625,251 54,914.28 207,292 407,182 46,288.48 214,422 409,392 42,334.82
“Average” tax rates 20 249,507,691 538,075,925 60,525.45 7,519,605 14,178,602 48,363.80 7,828,425 14,694,047 49,734.62
    Rising tax rates 2 17,953,889 38,180,685 59,644.70 330,576 607,380 49,560.19 413,799 739,294 51,277.42
    No tax rate change 13 176,704,206 385,778,036 59,395.20 4,910,694 9,386,687 46,889.42 5,089,826 9,692,682 49,094.16
    No tax rate change and Right to Work 4 64,379,032 145,280,565 54,703.45 1,917,459 3,743,967 44,397.42 1,850,417 3,645,737 43,863.70
    No tax rate change and not Right to Work 9 112,325,174 241,957,405 62,264.68 3,156,835 5,904,267 49,476.14 3,372,396 6,276,512 51,726.47
    Falling tax rates 5 54,849,596 112,657,270 64,085.50 2,114,735 3,922,988 50,112.65 2,191,813 4,032,504 51,335.11
    Falling tax rates and Right to Work 2 3,640,114 7,368,183 62,206.17 1,080,154 2,132,873 47,915.90 999,989 1,989,715 45,394.29
    Falling tax rates and Not Right to Work 3 51,209,482 105,289,087 64,219.09 1,034,581 1,790,115 52,406.17 1,191,824 2,042,789 56,319.70
    Low tax rates 10 93,025,151 200,974,538 57,580.30 3,010,989 5,852,434 47,849.31 3,170,276 6,109,980 46,197.62
    Falling tax rates 4 32,609,537 72,240,314 51,229.55 998,345 1,994,291 44,145.77 954,565 1,837,614 45,046.61
    Falling tax rates and Right to Work 3 20,916,843 46,179,472 53,379.88 375,509 760,740 41,570.15 336,915 668,426 44,050.70
    Falling tax rates and Not Right to Work 1 4,768,505 10,577,202 60,461.77 176,584 386,278 49,298.55 202,823 454,708 44,573.24
    No tax rate change 6 60,415,614 128,734,224 61,008.13 2,012,644 3,858,143 49,686.40 2,215,711 4,272,366 46,693.49
    Right to Work 7 50,152,112 11,1750,942 54,698.91 2,053,073 4,120,876 45,823.85 2,097,464 4,216,023 43,105.85
    Right to Work and No tax rate change 3 27,661,560 61,536,498 51,534.79 835,954 1,670,399 44161.64 812,470 16,07,044 43,493.13
    Right to Work and Falling tax rates 4 22,490,552 50,214,444 58,590.53 1,217,119 2,450,477 46,965.51 1,284,994 2,608,979 42,860.98
No income tax 7 129,052,291 280,378,754 60,006.63 4,143,328 7,959,051 57,166.79 3,746,822 7,064,477 47,035.77
    Right to Work 2 8,612,255 18,558,577 59,358.10 312,518 629,715 40,829.11 318,809 643,795 43,590.14
    Not Right to Work 5 120,440,036 261,820,177 60,053.00 3,830,810 7,329,336 58,499.62 3,428,013 6,420,682 47,356.21


The second panel reports the data for the “average” tax rate states. Again, a pattern emerges. The states with no significant tax rates and/or falling tax rates that also happen to be Right to Work are the only group of states showing a net gain from migration as well as a positive or net inflow of people. Notice also that on average the magnitude of the migration gains is smaller for the “average” income tax rate states than for the high income tax rate states.
The third panel shows that for the low tax rate states the groups experiencing a net outflow also experience an income gain. This fits our view that the people will migrate to improve their income levels even if they are in a low tax rate state. The biggest income gains is experienced by the groups of states that have a falling tax rate and are Right to Work states.
The fourth panel shows the states with no income tax rates; again the data shows that these groups of states show a net inflow of people and these groups of states also show the largest gains in income. The one anomaly here is that the Right to Work states show an unexpected result: a net outflow and a net income loss. But this makes some sense. People will move to areas where there are more opportunities. You would expect the lower income people the ones likely to gain an increase in income. One possibility that we have not discussed up to this point is how the social safety net may affect the migration level of the lower income groups. The differential in social safety net benefits may be an important factor for the lower income groups.
The data in the panels show that the income difference between the inflows and outflows are the largest for the most extreme tax rate changes. The gains are the largest for the no income tax rate states while the losses are the largest for the high-income tax rate states. Another result suggested by the data is that the interaction between the Right to Work and tax rates seems to break down for states with no income tax rate states. If as we argue that the Right to Work may be a proxy for the regulatory and overall environment, one can also argue that the no income tax rate state may also reflect similar environments. Hence, we would expect the Right to Work to be more important the higher the tax rates.

Brain Drain?

The findings reported in the previous section and the overall migration away from the high tax states to the other states is in line with the competitive environment framework that we have outlined. One concern is that the migration patterns are such that the people leaving the high tax states tend to have higher income than the people moving into the state thereby raising the possibility of a brain drain effect taking place in these high tax rate states economies.
To investigate this possibility, we chose a high tax state that is dear to our hearts, California, and examined the emigration and immigration patterns to and from high and low tax rate states and Right to Work states. Once we show that the patterns are consistent with the results already reported, we focus on the migration patterns with the neighboring/bordering states.
The results reported in Table 6.6 shows that California is only gaining people from states with high and rising or average tax rates, as well as from states with average and rising tax rates. More importantly, the people moving in from those states have a higher income than those moving out to those states. In this case, the brain drain is working in California’s favor. But sadly there are not that many states that have as high or higher tax rates than the state of California. For the remaining group of states, California is losing population to these states, in particular the Right to Work states or states with no income tax rates. The data shows that the people moving to these states have a higher income than those coming in from these states, a result that supports the brain drain hypothesis.

Table 6.6

California Migration by States’ Economic Environment Classified by Top State Income Tax Rates and Right to Work
Immigration Outmigration Net inflows
Returns Households AGI per household Returns Household AGI per household Returns Households AGI per households
Immigration 1,581,844 2,805,818 54,791.58 1,657,989 3,101,575 57,616.64 −76,145 −295,757 −2,825.06
High tax rates
Rising rates 108,493 176,931 67,798.04 83,341 140,770 58,227.81 25,152 36,161 9,570.23
Average rates 126,278 212,389 65,352.16 107,113 186,144 64,477.59 19,165 26,245 874.57
Falling rates 52,989 99,146 48,817.10 53,800 105,017 49,269.50 −811 −5,871 −452.41
Average tax rates
Rising rates 146,937 221,325 77,207.59 117,136 177,176 71,613.10 29,801 44,149 5,594.49
Average rates 312,070 563,603 51,714.69 323,549 621,294 55,148.54 −11,479 −57,691 −3,433.85
Falling rates 44,621 72,807 50,911.64 37,564 67,068 51,076.91 7,057 5,739 −165.27
Low tax rates
Rising rates
Average rates 94,055 16,2078 51,383.73 93,920 179,836 54,668.72 135 −17,758 −3,284.99
Falling rates 49,648 89,958 43,906.95 52,958 99,806 41,771.28 −3,310 −9,848 2,135.67
No income tax 378,267 703,309 53,884.39 450,248 885,974 60,309.37 −71,981 −182,665 −6,424.98
Right to Work 234,342 443,764 43,789.42 266,724 534,098 48,316.32 −32,382 −90,334 −4,526.89
Other states 1,079,016 1,857,782 60,317.62 1,052,905 1,928,987 60,949.37 26,111 −71,205 −631.74
Arizona 111,731 215,104 44,370.59 126,098 241,154 51,178.21 −12,353 −26,050 −6,807.62
Nevada 96849 183,937 38,387.15 88,178 239,428 60,921.42 −29,249 −55,491 −22,534.27
Oregon 59,906 105,231 44,252.83 83,341 157,908 50,287.85 −28,272 −52,677 −6,035.01

The data on the migration patterns with the neighboring states is also quite interesting and consistent with the results already reported. But one result stands out; the gains from moving to Arizona and/or Oregon are roughly the same, slightly better than $6000. However, the gains from moving to Nevada at $22,534.27 are almost four times larger than those of moving to Oregon and or Arizona. Recall that Oregon and Arizona were both designated as high tax rate states while Nevada has no state income tax rate. It is important to note that the people incoming from Nevada have an average income of $38,387.15 while those moving out have an income of $60,921.42. This number raises the issue as to why are these lower income people coming here from Nevada.
Notice that there is a net outflow to each of the neighboring states. It seems that California is like an exploding supernova sending jobs all over the United States’ universe and, in particular, its neighbors. If this is true, the neighboring states should erect statues to the governors of California. The state’s bad fiscal policies have caused a net emigration out of California to the benefit of the neighboring states.
The differences in taxation across the states explain the patterns of emigration as well as the AGI of the migrants to its neighboring states. Our basic hypothesis is simple: in the absence of any tax effect or any other impediment, we would expect that the migration out of California into neighboring states to be distributed in direct proportion to the relative sizes of the neighboring economies. For example, as Arizona accounts for 48.69% of the nonmigrant population of the region during the time period, all else the same, we would expect the state to capture 45.82% of the migration. Yet Arizona only accounts for 19.41% of the net flows. In contrast, Nevada with only 21.66% of the nonmigrant population accounts for 41.34% of the net migration flows.
Now tax differences and other transportation costs would affect the emigration pattern out of California. As Nevada is classified as a no income tax state, Arizona and Oregon as high rate states, the tax arbitrage hypothesis suggests that Nevada should gain a more than proportionate share of the emigration out of California. Nevada accounts for 21.66% of the neighbors’ nonmigrant population and yet it captures 41.34% of the net outflows from California to its neighbors.
So far we have been able to provide a tax-based explanation for the emigration out of California. However, the converse does not hold water. Looking at the tax rate data presented in Table 6.7, it is apparent that, on average, people would not move to California from Nevada for tax reasons. They may move from Oregon, the high tax state. The tax story would suggest that as far as immigration into California goes, Oregon should be an outperformer and Nevada, the no tax state, should be an underperformer. Yet as we look at the bottom half of Table 6.6, we find that this is not the case.

Table 6.7

Tax Brackets for California and its Neighbors
Income bracket California Arizona Nevada Oregon
$0 1.00% 2.59% 0.00% 5%
$6,700 1.00% 2.59% 0.00% 7%
$16,030 2.00% 2.50% 0.00% 7%
$16,900 2.00% 2.50% 0.00% 9%
$20,357 2.00% 2.88% 0.00% 9%
$38,002 4.00% 2.88% 0.00% 9%
$50,890 4.00% 3.36% 0.00% 9%
$59,978 6.00% 3.36% 0.00% 9%
$83,258 8.00% 3.36% 0.00% 9%
$101,779 8.00% 4.24% 0.00% 9%
$105,224 9.30% 4.24% 0.00% 9%
$250,000 9.30% 4.24% 0.00% 9.90%
$305,336 9.30% 4.54% 0.00% 9.90%
$537,500 10.30% 4.54% 0.00% 9.90%
$644,998 11.30% 4.54% 0.00% 9.90%
$1,074,996 12.30% 4.54% 0.00% 9.90%
$1,074,996 13.30% 4.54% 0.00% 9.90%

We have already hinted at the rationale for the possible migration patterns. The reason why many of these states have high tax rates is that they have a government that has enacted a multitude of social and other public spending programs. However, one of the requirements for enjoyment of the benefits is need. Hence to the extent that the public services are means tested, they will attract migrants from states with no such programs. Hence if the tax rate is a proxy for the spending levels, the progressivity of the state tax code and strict means testing is all we need to add to the mix. Then we can easily argue that the migration from lowest tax neighbor, Nevada, to California will be in excess of the states’ share, while the opposite will hold for the highest neighboring state, Oregon. The income data for the people coming into California at the bottom of Table 6.6 shows that this is the case.
The data clearly support our views that the high tax rates will induce the higher income taxpayers to emigrate and the provision of means tested public services will induce the immigration of lower income taxpayers. The net effect of these policies is a net outflow, as well as a “brain drain” that results in a net reduction in tax revenues per dollar worth of income. In addition, the expansion of public services not only attracts the taxpayers that will pass the means test (i.e., lower income taxpayers), but it will also result in an increase in public spending. The progressivity reduces the base for two reasons: there will be fewer people and they will have a lower income. Under a progressive tax code this will have a disproportionate effect on revenues. The end result is higher tax rates, lower revenues per capita, and higher spending per capita. The combination leads to a brain drain and that is not a good thing for the state’s finances. However, if our views are correct, the problem is reversible and its solution is an obvious one.

Summary

The states’ experiences enhance the supply-siders’ arguments as to why tax rate changes can have a significant impact on the tax base. Proponents of tax rate increases concede, in principle, the qualitative arguments that we are making. They just do not agree with the magnitude of the effects in question. Essentially what these economists are saying is that they don’t believe that these people will respond to the disincentives. If they do, the government should be ready to step up its enforcement to make sure it collects. But the one area that enforcement cannot help is to force people to work, hire workers, or invest.
On the issue of personal and corporate income taxation, there is a considerable disagreement as to what the impact of the tax rates on the economy and the tax base will be. Needless to say, proponents of the tax increases argue that the substitution effects are small or negligible, and will have no significant effect on the economy’s growth rate and/or tax revenues in the short or long run. We disagree. Our view is that to the extent these moves make the capital markets more efficient, the economy will benefit and so will the long run growth rate. The higher after-tax rates of return will increase the overall supply of labor and capital to the economy, thereby increasing the level of output and quite possibly the growth rate. What happens to tax revenue collections depends on the overall response. However, the story here suggests that the longer the horizon, the greater the flexibility of the economy to adjust and thus the larger the impact of the tax rate changes will be on the tax base.
The one major criticism that we have regarding the supply-side effects of the tax rates is that the critics focus mainly on the aggregate supply from a closed economy perspective. As we have already mentioned, this debate is about the magnitude of the response of the factors within the economy. We have made our views known in the previous paragraph. The critics believe that the supply response will be modest at best, where as we think it is much larger. We also think they are ignoring one very important effect that significantly underestimates the supply response. They have much to learn from the states’ experiences.
So, the big issue is whether the tax increase will slow down the pace of economic activity and thus, in the long run, reduce the tax base. To this they conclude that to reduce tax avoidance opportunities, tax rates on capital gains and dividends should be increased along with the basic rate. Closing loopholes and stepping up enforcement would further limit tax avoidance and evasion. However, that will not produce the desired results in the long run and quite possibly the short run too.
To make our point we need to make a parallel. Imagine equilibrium in an integrated economy, say the United States, consisting of a union of 50 states. Each of the states can be thought of an open economy where factors of production are free to move. The data shows that states with rising tax rates tend to suffer outmigration of both people and capital, and, as a result, a reduction in the tax base, while states with lower tax rates gain population, as well as experiencing a capital inflow and a tax base increase.
..................Content has been hidden....................

You can't read the all page of ebook, please click here login for view all page.
Reset